COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the document Proposals for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing the European Electronic Communications Code (Recast) and a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing the Body of European Regulators for Electronic Communications - Main contents
Document date | 04-10-2016 |
---|---|
Publication date | 05-10-2016 |
Reference | 12252/16 ADD 4 |
From | Secretary-General of the European Commission, signed by Mr Jordi AYET PUIGARNAU, Director |
External link | original article |
Original document in PDF |
Council of the European Union
Brussels, 4 October 2016 (OR. en)
12252/16
Interinstitutional File: ADD 4
2016/0288 (COD) i
TELECOM 165 COMPET 486 MI 578 CONSOM 215 IA 72 CODEC 1269
COVER NOTE
From: Secretary-General of the European Commission, signed by Mr Jordi AYET PUIGARNAU, Director
date of receipt: 14 September 2016
To: Mr Jeppe TRANHOLM-MIKKELSEN, Secretary-General of the Council of the European Union
No. Cion doc.: SWD(2016) 303 final/2 PART 3/3
Subject: COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the document Proposals for a Directive of the European
Parliament and of the Council establishing the European Electronic Communications Code (Recast) and a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing the Body of European Regulators for Electronic Communications
Delegations will find attached document SWD(2016) 303 final/2 PART 3/3.
Encl.: SWD(2016) 303 final/2 PART 3/3
EUROPEAN COMMISSION
Brussels, 3.10.2016 SWD(2016) 303 final/2
PART 3/3
CORRIGENDUM
Annule et remplace le SWD(2016) 303 final.
Suppression des liens vers des documents externes.
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT
IMPACT ASSESSMENT
Accompanying the document
Proposals for
a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing the European Electronic Communications Code (Recast) and
a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing the Body of European Regulators for Electronic Communications
{COM(2016) 590 final i} {COM(2016) 591 final i} {SWD(2016) 304 final} 6.6 ANNEX 6 - Data and problem evidence
6.6.1 Introduction
Europe's Digital Progress Report provides an overview of the progress made by MS in digitalisation. It also details the policy responses by MS to address the specific challenges that face them.
The Commission adopted the DSM Strategy for Europe 411 in May 2015, which identified that
Europe has the potential to lead in the global digital economy, but that fragmentation and barriers that do not exist in the single market are holding back the EU. It estimated that bringing down these barriers could contribute an additional EUR 415 billion to European GDP. The digital economy could expand markets and provide better services at better prices, offer more choice and create employment. The DSM could create opportunities for new start-ups and provide an environment for businesses to grow and benefit from a market of over 500 million consumers.
The Commission therefore announced a series of measures to be taken at EU level to:
• improve access for consumers and businesses to online goods and services across Europe;
• create the right conditions for digital networks and services to flourish; and • maximise the growth potential of the European digital economy.
The delivery rhythm of the announced measures has been brisk.
Already on 6 May 2015, the Commission launched a competition sector inquiry into eCommerce relating to the online trade of goods and the online provision of services. More than 1300 companies responded before the end of 2015. A first set of very preliminary results has been published on 18 March 2016, showing that geo-blocking is widespread in the EU. This is partly due to unilateral decisions by companies not to sell abroad but also contractual barriers set up by companies preventing consumers from shopping online across EU borders.
On 9 December 2015, the Commission presented a proposal for Directive on contracts for the
supply of digital content 412 as well as a proposal for a Directive on certain aspects concerning contracts for the online and other distance sales of goods 413 . The aim of these proposals is to remove barriers due to contract law differences. In addition, for the supply of digital content, once adopted, the Directive should set out clear and specific rights for consumers. Indeed, there is currently a clear gap in EU legislation in the area of defective digital content, as most MS do not have any legislation in place to protect consumers in the case of defective digital content.
On the same day, the Commission proposed a Regulation on the cross-border portability of online content services in the internal market 414 to allow people to travel with their online content. In other words, this Regulation should ensure that Europeans who have purchased films, series, sports broadcasts, games or e-books online can access them when they travel within the EU.
At the same time, the Commission published an action plan to modernise EU copyright rules, 415 which should make EU copyright rules fit for the digital age. This ‘political preview’ will be translated into legislative proposals and policy initiatives that take into account responses to several public consultations.
411
412
413
414
415
A set of measures to support and link up national initiatives for the digitisation of industry and related services across all sectors and to boost investment through strategic partnerships and
networks was adopted by the Commission on 19 April 2016. 416 This package also contains
concrete measures to speed up the standard setting process for ICT and an updated e-government action plan to modernise digital public services.
In addition to action at the European level, the DSM strategy recognised that such action needs to be complemented by actions taken at MS level, since a major part of policies which are essential for the development of the digital economy are formulated a national level. Moreover, MS are at very different stages in the development of the digital economy; some, for example, the Nordic countries, are among the most advanced in the world, while others still have a lot of catching up to do. Therefore, both policy priorities and the impact of the DSM will differ significantly from Member State to Member State.
This report combines the quantitative evidence from the Digital Economy and Society index (DESI) with country-specific policy insights. It keeps track of the progress made in digitalisation in the MS and provides important feedback for policy-making at EU level. To enable a better comparison between MS, this report also develops a cross-country analysis for the main dimensions of DESI. This report will feed into the analysis of MS’ economic and social challenges and the monitoring of national reform efforts carried out under the European Semester.
The report is structured in thematic chapters that examine one issue across all MS. The first section starts with connectivity, followed by human capital, before moving on to internet usage, the digitisation of industry and digital public service and finally R&D in ICT. This is followed by country chapters, each of which looks in the same order at the same issues, except for R&D, which is not covered at the level of MS.
6.6.2 The state of play on connectivity and the telecom sector
The Connectivity dimension of DESI looks at both the demand and the supply side of fixed and mobile broadband. Under fixed broadband it assesses the availability as well as the take-up of basic and high-speed NGA broadband and also considers the affordability of retail offers. On mobile broadband, the availability of radio spectrum and the take-up of mobile broadband are included.
On the fixed side, Luxembourg, the Netherlands and the UK are the strongest, and Poland, Romania, Slovakia and Bulgaria the weakest. NGA subscriptions are particularly advanced in Belgium, Romania, the Netherlands and Lithuania. As for mobile broadband, The Nordic countries (Finland, Sweden and Denmark) lead along with Estonia, while lowest figures were registered by Hungary, Greece and Portugal.
416
COM (2016) 176 i, (COM(2016) 178 i, COM(2016) 179 i, COM(2016) 180 i.
Table 33 - EU average of Connectivity Indicators in DESI 2016
DESI - Connectivity
Fixed broadband coverage (% of homes) 97%
Fixed broadband take-up (% of homes) 72%
Mobile broadband take-up (subs per 100 people) 75
Spectrum (% of spectrum harmonised) 69%
NGA coverage (% of homes) 71%
Subscriptions to fast broadband (% of subscriptions) 30%
Fixed broadband price (as a % of income) 1.3%
Figure 37 - Digital Economy and Society Index (DESI), Connectivity, 2016
Total telecom services revenues have declined by 10 % in Europe since 2012. EU telecom CAPEX has slightly increased in the same period.
Telecom operators in Europe generated less revenue than US operators. Revenues went down from EUR 237 bn in 2012 to EUR 213 bn in 2016 (forecasted) in Europe. At the same time, the US also reduced its figures from EUR 252 bn to EUR 240 bn, surpassing Europe despite its smaller population. There have been large increases in emerging markets, especially in China, where there is still relatively low take-up of telecom services 417 .
Figure 38 - Total telecommunication services revenues per region, billion EUR, 2012-2016
417 Note: this analysis is based on detailed figures from 26 MS, which covered about 98 % of the total EU market (total telecom carrier services).
Source: 2015 EITO in collaboration with IDC
CAPEX figures remained stable over the last four years even though NGA coverage increased from 54 % to 71 %. Mobile CAPEX spending represented 60 % of total spending.
Figure 39 - Share of fixed and mobile CAPEX in Europe, 2015
Mobile voice and fixed voice revenues have decreased by over 25 % since 2012. Mobile data grew by 10 %, and will represent over a quarter of total telecom revenues at EU level in 2016.
The revenues of the telecommunications sector went down by 10 % between 2012 and 2016 (forecasted figure).
Telecommunications revenues (carrier services) by segment showed, how voice services (both fixed and mobile) lost importance. Fixed voice decreased by 17.2 %, while mobile by 30.8 %. Fixed and mobile voice services made up 57 % of total telecom revenues in 2012, but will only represent 47 % in 2016.
Table 34 - Revenue growth rates, 2012-2016
Revenue growth rates 2012-2016
Telecom carrier services -10.0 %
Business data services -0.8 %
Fixed voice telephony -17.2 %
Internet access and services 13.1 %
Mobile data services 9.9 %
Mobile voice telephony -30.8 %
By contrast, the growth in mobile data services (9.9 % between 2012 and 2016) is remarkable. Mobile data will represent over one quarter of total market revenue (26 %) in 2016. The growth in mobile data services could not, however, compensate for the major decline in voice. Revenue from fixed internet access went up by 13.1 % since 2012, whereas business data services decreased by almost 1 % between 2012 and the forecasted figure for 2016, representing solely 7 % of total telecom revenue.
Figure 40 - Total telecom carrier services revenues by segment, 2012-2016
Source: 2015 EITO in collaboration with IDC
Coverage of next generation access (NGA) technologies continued to increase and reached 71 %. NGA deployments still focus mainly on urban areas, while only 28 % of rural homes are covered.
For the purpose of this report, next generation access includes VDSL, Cable Docsis 3.0 and FTTP. By mid-2015, Cable Docsis 3.0 had the largest NGA coverage at 44 %, followed by VDSL (41 %) and FTTP (21 %). Most of the upgrades in European cable networks had taken place by 2011, while VDSL coverage doubled in the last four years. There was remarkable progress also in FTTP growing from 10 % in 2011 to 21 % in 2015, but FTTP coverage is still low.
NGA networks are still very much limited to urban areas: only 28 % of rural homes are covered, mainly by VDSL.
Figure 41 - NGA broadband coverage in the EU, 2010-2015
Figure 42 - Next generation access (FTTP, VDSL and Docsis 3.0 cable) coverage, June 2015
Coverage of Fibre to the Premises (FTTP) grew from 10 % in 2011 to 21 % in 2015, while it remains a primarily urban technology. Lithuania, Latvia, Portugal and Estonia are the leaders in FTTP in Europe.
FTTP is catching up in Europe, as coverage for homes more than doubled since 2011. However, the FTTP footprint is still significantly lower than that of cable Docsis 3.0 and VDSL. In Estonia, Portugal, Latvia and Lithuania more than two thirds of homes can already subscribe to FTTP services, while in Greece, the UK, Ireland, Germany, Austria and Poland only less than 10 % can do so. FTTP services are available mainly in urban areas with the exception of Lithuania, Latvia, Estonia, Denmark and Luxembourg, where more than one in three rural homes can also have access to it.
Figure 43 - Fibre to the premises (FTTP) coverage in the EU, 2011-2015
Figure 44 - Fibre to the premises (FTTP) coverage, June 2015
4G mobile broadband availability reached 86%, up from 27% three years ago. 4G has been commercially launched in all MS.
In 2015, deployments of 4G (LTE) continued: coverage went up from 79% of homes to 86% in six months. Nevertheless, 4G coverage is still substantially below that of 3G (HSPA). As of October 2015, 80% of Mobile Network Operators in the EU offered 4G services on LTE networks.
LTE is most widely developed in the Netherlands, Sweden and Denmark, while commercial 4G services were launched only last year in Bulgaria.
LTE deployments have focused so far mainly in urban areas, as only 36% of rural homes are covered. However, in sixteen MS, LTE is already available also in the majority of rural homes, with very high rates in Denmark, Sweden, Slovenia, Luxembourg and the Netherlands.
Figure 45 - Mobile broadband coverage in the EU, 2011-2015
Figure 46 - 4G (LTE) coverage, June 2015
An estimated 8 % of European homes subscribe to ultrafast broadband (at least 100Mbps), up from 0.3 % five years ago. Romania, Sweden and Latvia are the most advanced in ultrafast broadband adoption.
The Digital Agenda for Europe set the objective that at least 50 % of homes should subscribe to ultrafast broadband by 2020. From June 2015, 49 % of homes are covered by networks capable of providing 100Mbps. As service offerings are emerging, take-up is growing sharply. The penetration is the highest in Romania, Sweden and Latvia. These three MS have a high coverage of FTTP. In Greece, Italy and Croatia take-up is low mainly due to the lack of superfast infrastructure, while in Cyprus and Malta, where the infrastructure is available for many homes, still mainly lower speed offers are purchased.
Figure 47 - Percentage of households with a fast broadband (at least 30Mbps) subscription at EU level, 2010-2015
Figure 48 - Percentage of households with an ultrafast broadband (at least 100Mbps) subscription, July 2015
FTTH and FTTB together represent 9 % of EU broadband subscriptions up from 7 % a year ago. In these technologies, Europe is still very much lagging behind South Korea and Japan.
Figure 49- Share of fibre connections in total fixed broadband, July 2015
Fast and ultrafast broadband subscriptions grew by 36 % in 12 months. In Belgium, Latvia and Romania, the majority of subscriptions are at least 30 Mbps. Ultrafast (at least 100 Mbps) is most widespread in Belgium and Romania.
Despite the growth in fast and ultrafast subscriptions, they are still rare in the EU. In January 2015, only slightly more than one in four subscriptions were at least 30 Mbps and only 9 % were at least 100Mbps.
In Belgium, Romania, Malta, Latvia, Portugal, Lithuania, Ireland, the Netherlands and Sweden, more than 50 % are already at least 30Mbps, while the same ratio is less than 10 % in Italy, Greece, Cyprus and Croatia. In ultrafast (at least 100 Mbps), Sweden, Latvia and Romania are the most advanced with more than 40 % of subscriptions.
Figure 50 - Fixed broadband subscriptions by headline speed at EU level, 2008-2015
Figure 51 - Fixed broadband subscriptions by headline speed, July 2015
There are 75 active mobile broadband SIM cards per 100 people in the EU, up from 34 four years ago. The growth was linear over the last three years with over 40 million new subscriptions added every year.
Mobile broadband represents a fast growing segment of the broadband market. More than 60% of all active mobile SIM cards use mobile broadband.
In the Nordic countries and Estonia, there are already more than 100 subscriptions per 100 people, while in Hungary, Greece, Portugal and Slovenia the take-up rate is still below 50%. Most of the mobile broadband subscriptions are used on smartphones rather than in tablets or notebooks.
Figure 52 - Mobile broadband penetration at EU level, January 2009 - July 2015
Figure 53 - Mobile broadband penetration at EU level, January 2009 - July 2015
Mobile broadband traffic: Tablets are expected to be the touchstone for mobile data traffic in 2020, exceeding smartphones and laptops in average usage. Mobile data traffic in 2020 is expected to be 6-fold higher than in 2015.
Mobile data traffic in Western Europe is expected to grow by 6-fold from 2015 until 2020, which represents a higher growth compared to the US (x6), South-Korea (x5) and Japan (x4). Indeed, mobile data traffic will grow 2 times faster than fixed IP traffic from 2015 to 2020.
The average smartphone user in Western Europe will generate 4.6 Gb of mobile data traffic per month in 2020, up by 353% from 2015. Laptop users will generate 4.4 Gb and tablets user more than 6GB.
Tablet devices in Europe will overtake mobile-connected laptops and smartphones in total data traffic. Currently, in Western Europe, tablets represent 33% of total mobile traffic. In 2020, their share will be 42%, while in South-Korea and Japan tablets will weigh less than 40% of total mobile traffic.
As for the US, tablets will represent 44% of total mobile traffic by 2020, with 9Gb per month per user, as opposed to 6Gb in the EU.
Figure 54 - Mobile data traffic per type of device and region, Megabytes per month, 2015 - 2020
Machine-to-Machine communications: In Western Europe, M2M modules currently generate 3% of total mobile data traffic. By 2020, this figure will go up to 11.6%, while M2M modules will represent more than half of the total connected mobile devices in Western Europe.
Machine-to-Machine communications on mobile networks will continue to increase rapidly both in terms of traffic and the number of devices. M2M currently represents 19% of all connected mobile devices; this ratio is forecasted to go up to 51% by 2020 in Western Europe. M2M traffic will also expand, but will still take a relatively low share of total traffic on mobile networks (12%).
The US and Japan will show similar figures, while in South Korea both traffic and number of M2M devices will be significantly higher proportionally.
Figure 55 - Percentage of M2M modules of device connections by region, 2015 - 2020
Figure 56 - M2M traffic as a percentage of total mobile data traffic by region, 2015 - 2020
Broadband take-up tends to be lower in MS where the cost of broadband access accounts for a higher share of income, but the correlation is not strong. The lowest income quartile of the EU population has a significantly lower take-up rate.
Considering overall take-up, European average is 72 % of homes with Luxembourg, the Netherlands at the highest positions and Italy, Bulgaria and Poland lagging behind.
Statistics show that income plays an important role in subscription rates. The lowest income quartile has only 51 % take-up of fixed broadband as opposed to 89 % in the highest income quartile.
The lag in the lowest income quartile when compared with the national average is evident in Bulgaria, Romania, Hungary, Slovenia, Lithuania, Czech Republic, Croatia, Spain and Slovakia.
Figure 57 - Fixed broadband household penetration by income quartiles at EU level, 2011-2015
Figure 58 - Household fixed broadband penetration and share of broadband access cost
(standalone 12-30Mbps download) in disposable income, 2015 418
Source: Commission services based on Eurostat and Van Dijk
Half of all EU households subscribed to bundled communications services in 2015. 80 % of bundles include internet access. Fixed telephony + internet is the most popular type of bundle.
418 Data not available for Luxembourg and Malta.
50 % of all EU households purchase bundled communications services, up from 38 % six years ago. The most popular bundle is fixed telephony + internet followed by ‘triple play’: fixed telephony + internet + TV. Internet access (either fixed or mobile) is present in 80 % of all service bundles, fixed telephony in 64 %, TV in 54 % and mobile telephony in 46 %.
Figure 59 - Percentage of households subscribing to bundled services at EU level, 2009-2015
Figure 60 - Popularity of different services in bundles at EU level, 2015
Figure 61 - Popularity of different bundles (% homes with subscriptions) at EU level, 2015
Prices of mobile voice+data plans vary greatly across Europe. In comparison with the US, the EU is cheaper for lower usage baskets, and more expensive for high-end packages.
Looking at the usage basket of 300 voice calls and 1GB data usage on handset, minimum prices range between €13 and €73 with an EU average of €31.
The cheapest countries are Estonia, Lithuania, Denmark and the UK with minimum prices below €15. At the same time, prices are very high (>€60) in Hungary, Malta and Greece.
The EU on average has much lower prices than the US for the 0.1GB+30 calls and the 0.5GB+100 calls baskets, however, on the 2GB+900 calls basket, the US is by close to 30%
cheaper than the EU 419 .
Figure 62 - Mobile broadband prices (EUR PPP) - handset use in the EU and the US, 2015
Figure 63 - Mobile broadband prices (EUR PPP) - handset use, 1GB + 300 calls, 2015
419 Source: SMART 2014/0049 - Mobile Broadband prices (February 2015) https://ec.europa.eu/digital-single
href="https://ec.europa.eu/digital-single-market/en/news/mobile-broadband-prices-february-2015">market/en/news/mobile-broadband-prices-february-2015. This study was carried out for the European Commission
by Van Dijk.
Prices of mobile broadband plans for laptops also show large differences across Europe. In comparison with the US, the EU is cheaper for all usage baskets.
Looking at 5GB data-only plans for laptops, minimum prices range between €10 and €46. The EU average (€19) is below the price of fixed standalone offers of 12-30Mbps.
The cheapest countries are Austria, Italy, Finland, Denmark and Poland with prices below €12. At the same time, prices are very high (>€30) in Cyprus, Spain, Czech Republic and Croatia.
The EU on average has much lower prices than the US for all the laptop baskets 420 .
Figure 64 - Mobile broadband prices (EUR PPP) - laptop use in the EU and the US, 2015
Figure 65 - Mobile broadband prices (EUR PPP) - laptop use, 5GB, 2015
420 Source: SMART 2014/0049 - Mobile Broadband prices (February 2015) https://ec.europa.eu/digital-single
href="https://ec.europa.eu/digital-single-market/en/news/mobile-broadband-prices-february-2015">market/en/news/mobile-broadband-prices-february-2015. This study was carried out for the European Commission
by Van Dijk.
6.6.3 Technical annex on technologies and medium
In the context of constantly increasing IP traffic, resources such as numbering or spectrum become more and more scarce. In spite of industrial development of more sophisticated and optimised solutions of spectrum usage for wireless data transmissions or of other transport media like copper or fibre, the laws of physics as currently understood are showing a clear unused capacity potential for certain technologies. Just comparing the fundamental properties of physical media available for future technologies which could appear over the air, copper or fibre, electrical signal speed is just two thirds of the speed of light. Fibre has an efficiency range of dozen of kilometres while copper G.fast is effective only over 250 m or so. More significantly, fibre theoretical capacity of frequency bandwidth is 50 000 GHz against 0.2 GHz for twisted copper.
Concerning broadband technologies we are observing on the one hand a tendency of boosting equipment around a copper pair or wireless path in order to use higher and higher spectrum in the fixed line or over the air over shorter and shorter distances; and on the other hand, evolution of optical devices in order to consume more and more of the unused already available spectrum of the fibre while keeping or improving the efficiency range.
As suggested by the SMART 2015/0005 support study, the continuous reliance on the existing copper-based infrastructure may hinder the development and take-up of certain applications if the most demanding scenario in terms of bandwidth needs materialises. The new concept of VHC takes into consideration a number of parameters in terms of quality of transmission (speeds, latency, jitter, etc.), that will define performance in a broader sense than understood today (with a current focus almost exclusively on download speeds).
Table 35 - Table of mediums and technologies
325
Shared
Typical Frequency
Medium Technologies Down/Upstream Efficiency medium Rate (1) (1) range latency
(5) for bandwidth Infrastructure architecture Suitability Future of the technology
(6)
lastmile?
Wi red
internet access by transmitting digital · use of existing telephone · further speed and range ADSL, ADSL2, 15-40 0,0022 data over the wires of a local telephone infrastructure improvements by enhancing and
ADSL2+ 24/1 Mbps 5 km ms no GHz network copper line terminates at · fast to install combining new DSL-based
telephone exchange (ADSL) or street · small efficiency range due to the technologies (phantom mode, cabinet (VDSL) line resistance of copper connection bonding, vectoring)
VDSL, VDSL2, 15-40 · Vectoring: Elimination of cross talks for lines · bridge technology towards
Vectori ng 100 /40 Mbps 1 km ms no 0,017 GHz higher bandwidths complete fibre optic cable
copper · G.Fast: Frequency increase up to 212 infrastructure MHz to achieve higher bandwidth
G.Fa s t 500/500 Mbps 250 m 15-40 ms no 0,212 GHz
· coaxial cable in streets and buildings; · use of existing cable television · Further implementation of new
fibre at the feeder segments infrastructure standards (DOCSIS 3.1) will allow 15-40
CATV 200/100 Mbps (4) 2-100 · network extensions to provide · fast to install to provide higher bandwidth to
km (2) ms yes 1 GHz backward channel functionality · high transmission rates end-users
Opti ca l
· signal transmission via fibre · highest bandwidth capacities · next generation technology to
p2p 0.3 ms no · distribution of signals by electrically · high efficiency range meet future bandwidth demands fiber 1/1 Gbps (a nd (5 µs powered network equipment or · high investment costs
unpowered optical splitters · bandwidth depends on the
more) 10-60 km per 50000 GHz transformation of the optical into
p2mp km) yes electronic signals at the curb (FTTC),
building (FTTB) or home (FTTH)
Wi reless
100/30 · mobile devices send and receive radio · highly suitable for coverage of · commercial deployment of new 5-10
LTE(Adva nced) (1000/30) 3-6 km signals with any number of cell site base remote areas (esp. 800 MHz) standards with additional features Mbps (3)
ms yes 0.1 GHz stations fitted with microwave antennas · quickly and easily implementable (5G) and provision of more
· sites connected to a cabled · shared medium frequency spectrum blocks (490 -
communication network and switching · limited frequencies 700 MHz) 30-70
HSPA 42,2 / 5,76 Mbps 3 km system · meets future needs of mobility ms yes 0.005 GHz
and bandwidth accessing NGA-
Services
· highly suitable for coverage of · 30 Mbps by 2020 based on next air
500- remote areas generation of high-throughput
Sa tellite 20/6 Mbps Hi gh 700 ms yes 10 GHz · quickly and easily implementable satellites
· run time latency
· asymmetrically
100 - 0.005- · inexpensive and proven · increased use of hotspots at
Wi -Fi 300/300 Mbps 300 m 1000 yes 0.160 · quickly and easily implementable central places ms GHz(7) · small efficiency range
· shared medium · gets continually replaced by Wi
Wi MAX 4/4 Mbps 60 km 50 ms yes 0.01 GHz Fi and LTE
Legend:
1 Technical standard max. 4 EuroDOCSIS 2 Depends on a mplification 5 Us ual practical va lues depending on distance
326
6.7 ANNEX 7 - Impact on competitiveness and innovation
6.7.1 Impact on competitiveness
The results of the CGE modelling also provide some indications as regards the implications of changes to the framework on labour productivity – one measure of EU competitiveness. In the cumulative scenario case, where preferred policy options are implemented in all areas, real labour productivity will exceed the baseline by an average of 1% for the period 2020-2025. This is equivalent to an average of 0.3 percentage points higher growth rate of productivity in the simulation scenario as compared to the baseline.
Figure 66 - Real labour productivity (preferred options vs status quo)
Source: Eurostat, own calculations
Viewed in international perspective, historically over the past quarter century labour productivity growth in EU has been lagging by an average of 0.4 percentage points as compared to the US and by
2.4 percentage points as compared to Korea (due its lower base). One can realistically expect productivity growth acceleration in the US and Korea in the forthcoming years as well. Despite this, the implementation of the considered policy changes should make a significant contribution towards boosting EU productivity, and potentially closing the gap.
Figure 67 - Trends in labour productivity – international comparisons
Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators database
6.7.2 Potential for disruptive change through innovation
The assumption underlying the CGE model is that clearer regulation of communication services and better connectivity will allow all sectors of the economy to operate more efficiently and realise higher total factor productivity rates.
In addition, the implementation of the preferred policy options might give a significant boost to innovation. Such innovation effects are particularly relevant in view of the fact that the review of the electronic communications framework could support the development and use of the ‘Internet of
Things’ (IoT) 421 and digitalization of industry inter alia by fostering:
-
-More regulatory certainty for all players throughout the IoT value chain contributing to a better investment climate;
-
-Levelling barriers for scaling up in Europe (by reducing regulatory heterogeneity) to the benefit of start-ups entering as new players shaping the IoT value chain.
-
-Improving connectivity for SIM based M2M services;
-
-End-users confidence about security, privacy and confidentiality 422 .
-
-Faster adoption of 5G; and
-
-A more ubiquitous roll-out of fibre networks to homes and lamp posts as to provide a backbone with the stability and low latency that is required by many IoT applications.
In turn, IoT implies an increased role for communication services in (and increased dependency on connectivity by) various industries, including automotive, agriculture, health, transport, etc. As such, policies which unlock the full potential of IoT and the digitization of industry could trigger a so-called
“disruptive growth path”. 423
It is not possible to estimate ex ante the impact of such structural economic changes on the basis of CGE modelling. Therefore, the CGE estimates should be treated as a lower bound. Assessing the impact of disruptive structure changes would require a case study approach examining how precisely production processes would change as a consequence of a progressing IoT. Such analysis has been done by McKinsey (2015) “The internet of things: mapping the value beyond the hype” which
analyses a number of IoT use cases 424 involving sectors that are key for EU competitiveness.
-
-IoT will particularly increase productivity and innovation in sectors that are considered essential for Europe’s global competitiveness (such as automotive 425 and electrical engineering 426 ). Realising the full potential of the IoT in Europe contributes to maintaining/strengthening that position. Not realising the full potential of the IoT in Europe may lead to other parts of the world overtaking that position.
421 BEREC (2016) and McKinsey (2015) identify a number of key enablers that contribute to unlocking the full potential of
the IoT. Key enablers are optimal fixed and mobile connectivity (which is realised through policy measures with regards to access, spectrum and numbering), regulatory security for new players in the IoT value chain (which is realised by clarifying the scope of the RF) as well as end-users confidence about security, privacy and confidentiality.
422 The reason, as explained by BEREC and McKinsey, is that new categories of risks are introduced by the Internet of
Things. McKinsey argues that more devices means more opportunities for potential breaches and BEREC argues that “[d]ue to limited resources in terms of energy and computing power, […] IoT devices may be vulnerable to cyber-attacks”.
Furthermore, McKinsey argues that the impact of a data breach is much larger in the context of the IoT. “when IoT is used to control physical assets, whether water treatment plants or automobiles, the consequences associated with a breach in security extend beyond the unauthorized release of information—they could potentially cause physical harm”. BEREC concludes that “If users do not trust that their data is being handled appropriately there is a risk that they might restrict or completely opt out of its use and sharing, which could impede the successful development of IoT.”
423 See: “Information Technologies and Labour Market Disruptions - A Cross-Atlantic Dialogue” background document by the
“interdisciplinary, cross-sector roundtable organised by the European Commission (DG Enterprise and Industry and DG Communication Networks, Content and Technology) in cooperation with The Conference Board and Cornell University ILR
School” 3/11/2014, p. 11
424 Outside, Home, Human, Cities, Factories, Worksites, Offices, Retail, environments, and Vehicles,
425 BEREC BoR(16)39 as well as McKinsey (2015) identify automotive as key sector that will adopt IoT applications. At the same time, it considered a strategic sector of the EU economy http://ec.europa.eu/growth/sectors/automotive/index_en.htm
426 Electrical engineering is a sector in which the EU is the global leader and which will benefit greatly from the ongoing growth in mobile devices see: http://ec.europa.eu/growth/sectors/electrical-engineering/index_en.htm
-
-IoT will also increase productivity and innovation in as well as in agriculture 427 which is an essential sector for the regional competitiveness of Europe’s peripheral areas 428 .
-
-Furthermore, IoT contributes to cost savings in a wide variety of other sectors such as E-health, smart metering/grids, smart homes and cities, etc.
McKinsey estimates for the global economy that by 2025, the full potential of IoT amounts to approximately 3.9 to 11.1 trillion dollars per year (including consumer surplus). In terms of % of global GDP this amounts to 3.3% to 9.4% according to our own calculations. 429 If Europe could realise a similar gain by fostering key IoT enablers, this would amount to an additional GDP of 0.56 and 1.59 trillion euros in the year 2025. 430
The contributions to European competitiveness that could be made from the proposed changes to the EU regulatory framework are summarised in the following table.
427 BEREC BoR(16)39 as well as McKinsey (2015) identify agriculture as key sector that will adopt IoT applications.
428 Thissen, van Oort, and ( Diodato (2013
429 On the basis of data and forecasts provided by the Conference board, global GDP may grow from 88 trillion dollars in
2015 to 117 trillion dollars in 2025, not accounting for a disruptive boost like the IoT. As such, the IoT may create up to 3.3% to 9.4% additional income at global level by 2025. See https://www.conferenceboard.org/data/economydatabase/index.cfm?id=27762 and https://www.conferenceboard.org/data/globaloutlook/index.cfm?id=27451
430 Assuming the EU economy has grown to 16.58 trillion euros by 2025 (based on forecasts by the Conference board). 0.33% of 16.58 trillion euros = 0.56 trillion euros. 9.4% of of 16.58 trillion euros = 1.59 trillion euros
Table 36 - Overview of competitiveness impacts
Access Spectrum Services Cost High bandwidth The prevalence of general The reduction of competitiveness connectivity supports the authorisations will make administrative burden
digitalisation of services, access to spectrum more and of regulatory reducing cost and time to affordable and lower heterogeneity realises market. Standardising administrative / cost savings for telecom wholesale products used regulatory costs. This is operators. for business should also of particular benefit to reduce costs and increase smaller companies with efficiency within crossmore limited resources border organisations
International Access policies are likely Device manufacturers Less regulatory competitiveness to boost infrastructure will benefit from EU heterogeneity contributes deployment in Europe, single market, offering to the realisation of a closing the investment significant scaling digital single market gap with other economies. opportunities, and which facilitates a faster Increased bandwidth is producing devices that are scale-up of European likely over time to able to operate in start-ups in the global support increased use of “European” bands. digital economy. digital services and the attractiveness of the EU as a platform for technological and service development. Innovation The deployment of fibre The prevalence of general More clarity and equality competitiveness to lampposts and homes authorisation will open up throughout the value supports 5G development, spectrum access to chain with regards to and new applications. A innovative services, faster regulation reduces connected economy may roll-out of 4G/5G will regulatory risk for new also drive disruptive foster development of (small medium sized and change in business new services based in large) players. This processes Europe. increases their willingness to invest and innovate
330 A key challenge however in realizing the benefits we have identified from innovations including those stemming from IoT is the capability of European businesses to leverage innovation. For example, comparing EU 431 innovation capacity and results against peer economies, according to the Global Innovation Index for 2015, 432 the EU seems to be lagging behind in terms of many aspects of innovation, 433 although some countries within Europe including Finland, Sweden,
Luxembourg, Denmark and Germany are reported to be relatively strong in making use of innovations specifically in ICT.
Source: Global innovation index, own calculations
If benefits are to be fully realized, this highlights the need for levelling up within Europe, not only in terms of supply-side policies for electronic communications including the regulatory environment, but also – importantly – on initiatives to support the absorption of new technologies within businesses of all sizes.
431
EU figures are derived aggregating the member states scores, weighting them with the respective country population.
432
The Global Innovation Index is an annual ranking of countries by their capacity for, and success in, innovation. It is published by INSEAD and the World Intellectual Property Organization, in partnership with other organisations and institutions. It is based on both subjective and objective data derived from several sources, including the International Telecommunication Union, the World Bank and the World Economic Forum.
433 There are clear differences for the business sophistication pillar of the index, which includes knowledge workers
and R&D activities performed in the business sector, links between the business sector and the academia and means
of knowledge absorption. Another aspect where EU is performing relatively worse concerns indicators for
‘knowledge and technology’ including knowledge creation, diffusion and impact.
6.8 ANNEX 8 – Options diagrams
6.8.1 Access options
Option 1 Do nothing
Option 2 Streamline market analysis Maintain current situation / flexibility
Option 3 Streamline market analysis Focus regulation for NGA Standardise business wholesale products
Option 4 Move to dispute resolution Limit regulation/remedies
6.8.2 Spectrum options
6.8.3 USO options
Option 1 Do nothing
Option 2 excluding public payphones and accessory services
Option 3 excluding public payphones and accessory services Basicbroadband affordability
Option 4 excluding PATS Basic broadband availability and affordability
6.8.4 Services options
Costs
Green shaded : moderate enforcement, compliance and adjustment costs Orange shaded : costs in terms of less privacy protection Red shaded : high regulatory enforcement and compliance costs + increased regulatory risks Blue shaded : costs of reduction in national flexibility
(size of which depends on heterogeneity of preferences and degree of harmonisation of horizontal rules)
6.8.5 Governance
Do nothing
Option 1
Enhanced advisory role
strenghtened competencies Extended NRA competencies Improved RSPG process for
(consumer protection, opinions & reports Harmonisation minimum set NRAs numbering, authorisation, Exchange of best practices on competencies and alignmented with BEREC geographical surveys ) aligned spectrum assignments
tasks, Enhanced BEREC advisory role with BEREC advisory tasks
Option 2 New governance: Chairperson, new single
Board, Executive Manager
Advisory and normative powers Commission/BEREC Double lock for BEREC peer review on notified
Harmonisation minimum set NRAsS coherence in market review spectrum assignment & competencies (including spectrum) mechanisms (remedies) recommendations
Option 3 and alignmented with BEREC tasks BEREC new tasks including binding
BEREC & RSPG advisory role and certain powers (transnational markets, normative powers for BEREC cross-border disputes
New governance: Chairperson, new single Board, Executive Manager with binding suppervisory and
enforcement powers
Option 4 EU regulator 6.9 ANNEX 9 - The connectivity strategy: a European Gigabit Society
This annex spells out the rationale behind the connectivity strategy for a European Gigabit Society by 2025. The Communication accompanying the review of the telecoms framework will introduce the policy context and the ambitions for Europe in the coming years. In this annex we review the process followed and the evidence underpinning the need for a Gigabit society.
6.9.1 The public consultation on internet speeds and the new ambitions
Adequate connectivity is a prerequisite to achieve a genuine DSM. This is why the DSM Strategy announced that the review of the Telecom Framework's focus would include "incentivising investment in high speed broadband networks". This is also why President Juncker and VP Katainen have made of telecommunciations one of the prioritiy areas for strategic investment under the regulation setting up the European Fund for Strategic Investment. DG CONNECT has then, over the last year, gathered evidence on Internet connectivity needs beyond 2020:
• We have held bilateral meetings not just with the telecom operators but also with various user sectors' representatives.
• We have analysed connectivity facts and figures in available publications and forecasts.
• We have carried out and analysed a full public consultation which focused on speed and quality of internet services.
Overall, the results of these various actions converge: the use of Internet services and applications will substantially increase for both fixed and mobile connectivity and there is a need to prepare now for higher speed (upload and download) and other features of quality of service (latency, resilience, etc.) beyond 2020. The findings of these various steps illustrate the need to:
-
1.Show greater ambition in terms of both average and maximal speed and other quality parameters beyond 2020, considering expected future developments and the time horizon for investment.
-
2.Ensure that policy, regulatory and financing instruments support an investment-friendly environment in line with such ambition.
These conclusions echo the call for a definition of Europe's connectivity ambition beyond 2020 from the participants - representatives of the industry, users and local and national public authorities - in the broadband roundtables that Commissioner Oettinger chaired in early 2015. These stakeholders called for defining long-term connectivity ambitions and for better rules and instruments to further deploy broadband infrastructure.
On the need to show greater and longer-term ambition and in line with the mandate given to Commissioner Oettinger by President Juncker to "set clear long-term strategic goals to offer legal certainty to the sector and create the right regulatory environment to foster investment and innovative businesses", Commissioner Oettinger announced in March his ambition of connectivity for a European gigabit society by 2025, to be based on 3 pillars:
• Gigabit connectivity for socio-economic drivers, starting with schools, hospitals, libraries, public administration and business centres.
• Future-proof ubiquitous connectivity to support all forms of mobility. • Improved connectivity in rural areas.
While the DAE targets should remain valid up to 2020, the expected uses' evolution and technological developments as well as the time horizon for investment (investment cycles needed for such broadband infrastructure projects run over 5-10 years) call for setting up now longer term objectives for 2025. A study is currently being conducted by the Commission Services to assess the feasibility of the three pillars announced by Commissioner Oettinger and
come up with a preliminary estimate of the cost entailed. 434
6.9.2 Connectivity and its importance
As mentioned in the main report and in the support studies, there are numerous studies showing that improved Broadband access is beneficial for the society. The positive impact ranges from purely economic GDP growth and unemployment decrease, through battling digital divide and improvement in innovativeness for business and increased employees skills to entertainment possibilities and wellbeing generated by e-health. EGovernment solutions decrease the costs of the local administration and the citizens are more willing to participate in community life (e.g. voting participation).
Czernich et al (2011) 435 examined the wider effects of broadband on GDP per capita across the OECD countries, finding that a 10-percentage point increase in broadband penetration raises national annual per capita growth by 0.9-1.5 percentage points. EIB and IMIT 436 study proves that higher Broadband speed has positive impact on GDP and it is greater in countries with lower income than countries with higher income. Katz et al. (2010) 437 claims that Germany achieving both the broadband penetration and speed targets will create more than 960,000 additional jobs and output worth more than 170 billion euro. Rohman and Bohlin 438 (2012) show that increasing the Broadband speed in the OECD countries stimulates GDP growth. The impacts depend on the broadband speed and the existing economic growth in particular country.
Studies conducted by De Stefano et al. (2014) 439 , Kandilov et al. (2011) 440 , Kim and Orazem (2012) 441 , Whitacre et al. (2014a) 442 show that Broadband can increase the number of businesses
– either because it increases firm entry, or because it helps with firms’ survival. Akerman et al.
(2015) 443 , Dettling (2013) 444 , Kolko (2012) 445 , Whitacre et al (2014b) 446 show that Broadband
can positively impact on local employment. Employment effects can vary across different types of areas, industries, and workers, with urban areas, service industries and skilled workers possibly benefiting more than rural areas, manufacturing industries and unskilled workers.
Forzati and Mattsson (2012) 447 show that increasing in the ratio of the population that lives
434
See SMART 2015/0068
435
Czernich N., Falck O., Kretschmer T., Woessmann L. (2011), Broadbnad Infrastructure and Economic Growth, The Economic Journal 121 (552) May 12, pp, 505-532
436
http://institute.eib.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/04/EIB_broadband-speed_120914.pdf
437 Katz, R. L., Vaterlaus, S., Zenhäusern, P. & Suter, S. (2010). The Impact of Broadband on Jobs and the German
Economy. Intereconomics , 45 (1), 26-34
438
Rohman, I. and E. Bohlin (2012), Does broadband speed really matter as a driver of economic growth? Investigating OECD countries. International Journal of Management and Network Economics, 2012, vol.2, issue 4, pages 336-356
439
De Stefano, T., Kneller, R., Timmis, J., (2014), The (Fuzzy) Digital Divide: The Effect of Broadband Internet Use on UK Firm Performance. University of Nottingham Discussion Papers in Economics. Discussion Paper 14/06.
440
Kandilov, AMG, Kandilov, IT, Liu, X, Renkow, M., (2011), The Impact of Broadband on U.S. Agriculture: An Evaluation of the USDA Broadband Loan Program. Selected paper Prepared for Presentation at the Agricultural and Applied Economics Association’s 2011 AAEA & NAREA Joint Annual Meeting. Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania, July 24- 26
441
Kim, Y., Orazem, P., (2012), Broadband Internet and Firm Entry: Evidence from Rural Iowa. Iowa State University Working Paper No. 12026
442
Whitacre, B., Gallardo, R., Strover, S., (2014a), Broadband's Contribution to Economic Growth in Rural Areas: Moving Towards a Causal Relationship. Telecommunications Policy 38, 1011-1023.
443 Akerman, A., Gaarder, I., Mogstad, M., (2015), The Skill Complementarity of Broadband Internet. Quarterly Journal of Economics.
444
Dettling, L.J., (2013), Broadband in the Labor Market: The Impact of Residential High Speed Internet on Married Women’s Labor Force Participation. Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.
445
Kolko, J., (2012), Broadband and Local Growth. Journal of Urban Economics 71, 100–113.
446
Whitacre, B., Gallardo, R., Strover, S., (2014b), Does Rural Broadband Impact Jobs and Income? Evidence from Spatial and First-Differenced Regressions. The Annals of Regional Science 53, 649-670.
447
Forzati and Mattsson (2012), The economic impact of broadband speed: Comparing between higher and lower income countries
within 353 metres of a fibre-connected premise contributes positively to job employment from
0%-0.2% after two and a half years. Atkinson et al (2009) 448 proved that investment in
broadband networks for USD 10 billion in one year generated about 498 thousand jobs in the
USA.
Table 37 -Potential socio-economic impacts of broadband deployment in Rural, Remote and
Sparsely populated areas
Domain Impacted Examples of benefits in RRS areas by stakeholders aspect
([B] business, [C] citizens)
Community Quality of life Participation in social life reducing geographical distances building (including politics, leisure activities, etc.) [C].
Interaction among citizens allowing for the participation of
Social inclusion a larger set of stakeholders (including elderly people,
minorities, people living in remote areas, etc.) [C].
Crime and Quality of life Reduction of crime due to the deterrent of remote public safety surveillance (e.g. safer small villages) [C]. Control of
strategic assets/infrastructures located in areas not easily accessible (e.g. increasing security and response capacities to man-made damages or natural disasters) [B].
Education and Competiveness Increase of productivity [B]. Increased contacts with skills and innovation research and innovation actors (i.e. universities and
enterprises) allowing connections and technology transfer processes at distance [B].
Increase of competitiveness on the job market with skills
Employment alignment with those of the citizens of urban areas [C]. Creation of ICT professional competences as a side effect
of deployment and management of broadband
infrastructures [C]. Improvement in the ICT take-up
Technological (eServices, eCommerce, eGovernment) [C] [B].
skills Increase of education delivered in remote mode facilitating
access to knowledge also by those having difficulties in accessing transport networks (from disabled people to people living in areas poorly covered by public transport services)[C]. |
Social inclusion
Economy Employment Selection and employment of workers at distance, accessing competences not available locally or located in areas not attractive for business [B]. Opportunity for workers to contribute remotely to specific ICT-based jobs [C].
Creation of new ICT-based businesses [B].
Increase of the Total Factor Productivity of the areas [B]. Increased competitiveness of local firms in other sectors
Growth than ICT through the creation of new/innovative products and services [B].
Competiveness
448
Atkinson, R.T., Castro D., Ezell S.J. (2009), "The digital Road to Recovery: A Stimulus Plan to Create Jobs, Boost Productivity and Revitalize America", The Information Technology and Innovation Foundation (ITIF)
and innovation Face-to-face communications worldwide, saving travels
costs and time [B]. Access of remote technological services to increase firms’ efficiency (i.e. cloud computing) while avoiding local physical installation of ICT equipment [B]. Implementation/adoption of logistic solutions addressed to
Incremental cost increase firms’ efficiency (i.e. monitoring of stocks) while saving avoiding traditional transport and logistics [B].
Incremental Direct access to global markets [B] and potential gaining of revenues a market share through eCommerce solutions [B].
Environment Incremental cost Use of smart grids with energy efficiency benefits [B] [C]. saving Less physical travels, implying reduced CO2 emission and use of fuels and time [B] [C]. Adoption of remote control
Quality of life systems to prevent and mitigate natural disasters [C].
Equality and Employment Job opportunities for disabled people or people not served well-being by public transport means [C]. Education opportunities for
Technological disabled people or people not served by public transport skills means [C]. Connection opportunities with families/relatives
Quality of life displaced in different areas [C]. Connection opportunities through smartphones and tablets [B] [C]. Connection Social inclusion opportunities for disabled people or people not served by public transport means [C]. Opportunities to access
Incremental cost information and data worldwide [B] [C]. Opportunities to saving save money from traditional telecommunications means
(i.e. fixed lines) [B] [C]. Opportunities to access eCommerce and eGovernment services [B] [C].
Finance and Wealth Valorisation of the value of an area reflected in increased wealth prices for housing/business location [B] [C]. Opportunities
Incremental cost to access financial services for disabled people, people not saving served by public transport means, and remotely located
businesses [B] [C].
Health care Incremental cost Reduction of costs for health consultations (for less critical saving pathologies) [C]. Digitalisation and automation of administrative procedures within public and private health
Quality of life systems [B] [C]. Monitoring of basic health conditions
through mobile apps [C]. Monitoring of patients at distance without requiring hospitalisation (for less critical pathologies) [C].
Source: Linking the Digital Agenda to rural and sparsely populated areas to boost their growth potential – Committee of the Region Report (2016)
SMART 2015/0005 demonstrates the impact of speed (and therefore quality) of networks. It estimates that an annual increase of broadband speeds of 21% (associated with a scenario whereby projected ADSL connections were all replaced with FTTC/VDSL connections by 2025), would result in cumulative growth in GDP of 1.5% by 2025. A 28% annual increase in speed (as would be associated with a replacement by all broadband connections with fibre) would result in cumulative growth in GDP by 2025 of 5.1%.
According to Vodafone and Arthur D. Little the number of fields which could benefit from the high-speed connectivity is substantial:
Better Healthcare: Fibre networks will be crucial for Digital Health such as Remote patient monitoring, Remote care & rehabilitation, Professional operative consultations and Research (e.g. Next Generation Genome Sequencing). Patient services are being improved, healthcare is delivered in a more efficient way, more patients can be reached and benefit from specialists’ attention and the cost of healthcare will ultimately be reduced. This sector still relies on antiquated infrastructure and many ‘pre-Digital’ working practices today.
Better Education: New educational tools and applications are being enabled by fibre networks such as immersive virtual reality training for professionals and remote interactive learning. Fibre networks will support increased digitalization within the classroom (e.g. to download content on tablets or laptops). This has allowed education to become more personalized, tailored to the need of each individual by student, increasing buy-in and motivation. Moreover, a larger network of students can be reached, teaching tasks distributed and education delivered in a more efficient way.
Increased Security: Monitoring public or private environments, recognizing suspicious activity and alerting security services can happen better and faster when fibre networks are in place. More and higher quality images can be captured (subject to privacy safeguards) and analysed whilst AI can recognize potentially dangerous situations and automatically trigger emergency response.
Positive Social impact: Fibre networks enable a range of new applications for entertainment, collaboration and social inclusion. Social relationships between people can be maintained regardless of distance, age or level of mobility, e.g. through high definition video streams or ambient presence.
Positive impact on Environment: Next Generation Smart Grid and Smart Mobility applications can be enabled by fibre networks and will have a positive impact on Energy consumption and CO2 emissions. Applications like Automated Energy Demand Response reduce the production and consumption, enabling more efficient use of renewables. Smart highways, Autonomous transportation and Smart traffic management tools – with core fibre networks – will lead to more efficient Mobility.
Increased Employment: New jobs are created to construct and set up the new fibre infrastructure. But more importantly, new applications and business models enabled by fibre networks appear and create new job opportunities, and the wider availability of such connectivity nationwide also distributes economic benefits and promotes modern commerce outside urban centres.
The benefits from the network and especially high-speed network are well documented but the value of benefits varies with the speed and scope of adoption, and in turn speed and scope of adoption depends on the quality of networks. This circularity renders decisions difficult, in particular for public investment.
6.9.3 Towards the Digital Single Market and new connectivity ambitions
The DSM Strategy stresses the importance of connectivity and ICT networks: they "provide the backbone for digital products and services which have the potential to support all aspects of our lives, and drive Europe's economic recovery"; the DSM "must be built on reliable, trustworthy, high-speed, affordable networks".
Adequate connectivity is a prerequisite to achieve a genuine DSM. This is why the DSM Strategy announced that the review of the Telecom Framework's focus would include "incentivising investment in high speed broadband networks". This is also why President Juncker and VP Katainen have made of digital networks one of the prioritiy areas for strategic investment under the regulation setting up the European Fund for Strategic Investment.
The lag between policy, investment and its impact on the society implies that in order to ensure connectivity beyond 2020 the decisions have already to be taken. Europe's future economic success will stem from innovation and new business models that will make the most of digital networks – not just telecom infrastructure, but also cloud computing, Big Data, connected cars, the digitalisation of our industry, and so on. Hence, a supply driven approach would be in line with ensuring access to these new paradigms, even if demand may not follow immediately. Policy aiming at increasing European competitiveness and attractiveness for business will improve EU wealth and contribute to the well-being of all the citizens, stimulating jobs creation and decreasing unemployment.
6.9.4 Technological developments
Our review of global IP traffic, technological trends, user scenario forecasts and the infrastructure needs for key policy initiatives further reinforces the view that networks require a true generational shift in terms not only of download speed, but also in other quality aspects such as upload speed, low latency, reduced jitter and uninterrupted access. The figure below illustrates the technological development, which will require better networks.
Figure 68 – Key applications and technological developments
Source: ADL
As mentioned in annex 6, section3, in the context of constantly increasing IP traffic, resources such as physical infrastructures, numbering or spectrum become more and more scarce. Furthermore, copper-based infrastructures tend to have a much higher number of nodes and equipment as well as require a higher amount of electricity. This implies higher maintenance costs and longer down periods which represent obstacles to the efficient and reliable running of these critical infrastructures. The figure below illustrates the differences between technologies.
Figure 69 – Network features and speeds
Source: European Commission
Additionally, despite the higher initial expenditure in terms of CAPEX, the maintenance and operational costs OPEX are lower for fibre based technologies. The graph below is an example of a business case from OAN project Southern Primorska. The higher initial costs are offset after less than 3 years of operations assuming take-up of 50%.
Figure 70 – Cost scenarios for Southern Primorska region
Source; European Commission elaboration on data from project Southern Primorska
Hence, the physical characteristics of certain media make them inherently better than other media for communication tasks. Extended reliance on the existing copper-based infrastructure is already today showing inefficiencies in terms of quality of transmission (speeds, latency, range, etc.), capacity, maintenance costs, energy and suitability, inflexibility to easily accommodate Software Defined Networks and the service innovation that this brings with them.
6.9.5 Some future developments
The cloud technology, also referred to as XaaS being X as a service, where X might mean Infrastructure, Software, Security, etc. becomes more and more popular. Investment in IT is usually costly and might generate additional costs in order to satisfy peak demands. Companies, which use cloud solutions only pay for capacity actually employed and do not need huge upfront investment (CAPEX). Below there are 2 graph illustrating the benefits from the cloud solutions – the left one represents a case, where a company invest in IT step by step and the right one the company, which benefits from the cloud.
Figure 71 – benefits from adopting a cloud solution
Source:medium.com
In order to benefit from the cloud the economic actors have to be connected – outsourcing IT capability requires excellent connectivity (both download and upload). Therefore for the connectivity is extremely important if Europe is supposed to get on the cutting edge of innovation by creating appropriate environment for the companies to optimize their costs. According to Cisco IP worldwide traffic will be growing very dynamically as the number of users and devices is fuelled by Internet of Things development.
Global IP traffic 2014 2019 Annual run rate 718.2 Exabytes 2.0 Zettabytes Traffic per capita 8 GB 22 GB
Globally, average IP traffic will reach 511 Tbps in 2019, and busy hour traffic will reach 1.7 Pbps. In 2019, the gigabyte equivalent of all movies ever made will cross Global IP networks every 2 minutes. Good connectivity will be key in order to ensure the wellbeing of the citizens.
Figure 72 – Cisco VNI forecasts
Penetration of Internet users, especially the business one will increase in the next 5 years and the trend will most likely continue till 2025.
Figure 73 - Internet of Things Units Installed Base by Category (Millions of Units)
Source: Gartner (November 2015)
New applications requiring low latency and VHC internet access are emerging and will create the demand for better connectivity. Figure 74 illustrates that a number of applications will need latency around 1ms and bandwidth of 1Gbps by 2025. Of course, one has to consider that many of these application will be run in parallel, so that the bandwidth needed by households is cumulative.
Figure 74 – Latency and speed needed by applications and services
6.10 ANNEX 10 – Problem drivers
The present annex provides a more detailed description of the drivers included in section 1.3 and of the evidence supporting them.
6.10.1 The lack of incentives to deploy networks in the absence of infrastructure competition or in rural areas
The rules governing the sector fell short of providing sufficient incentives and opportunities for the market-funded roll-out of NGA and especially VHC fixed and mobile networks. Moreover the deployment of wireless infrastructure was hampered by insufficient availability of a key resource i.e. spectrum.
The need for upgrades to legacy networks described under section 1.2.1 raises questions of whether there are sufficient incentives to invest in the upgrade, and also which competitive model should be applied, as the unbundling of the copper local loop from the central office may become relatively less important because of the performance improvements on the basis of other
technologies. 449
The transition from copper-based networks towards fibre-based networks is gradually happening worldwide. In Europe, fibre is being deployed by a variety of operators in the access network to overlay or replace legacy copper lines or even parts of HFC co-axial networks. One of the main challenges for regulators today is to incentivise investment and support sustainable competitive models for newly constructed networks, at the same time guaranteeing the attained level of access to legacy networks until those become redundant. MS have followed different strategies with varying outcomes, 450 and new broadband gaps have emerged in terms of coverage and takeup of NGA and VHC networks between countries in Europe, between Europe and international competitors 451 and between urban and rural households, which projections suggest may persist.
Deployment of VHC networks can be comparatively more expensive in near-term Capex than incremental upgrades of legacy copper infrastructures and demand for - VHC connectivity is very closely related to experience, hence requiring a supply-led ("build it and they will come") approach. Traditional network operators managing depreciated legacy infrastructures do not necessarily see the benefit of rolling out VHC broadband networks under these conditions, which in turn renders perceived business cases uncertain, especially in challenge areas that in any case can only support one network, such as rural areas.
Certain elements of the current regulatory framework, in the light of the most recent market developments could be improved to foster deployment of VHC networks, such as:
(i) Incumbent operators fear that they will be most likely price regulated, potentially on cost oriented basis if and where they deploy VHC networks, lowering their return on investment.
(ii) Insufficient regulatory predictability regarding access obligations on NGA networks (in particular pricing); due to short market review cycles, lack of sufficient focus on retail markets and the difficulty of enforcing consistency on the basis of non-binding recommendations, impacting network roll-out. Conversely for regulated operators, obligations to share on a nondiscriminatory basis any new assets may take away some of the incentives, especially for the riskiest investments.
449
Local Loop Unbundling has been the main tool facilitating competitive stimulus. LLU volumes are already starting to decline in countries such as Germany, with the migration to next generation fibre networks, and several countries such as the Netherlands and Sweden have focused on fibre access..
450
See SMART 2015/0002 for a detailed analysis of regulatory strategies and outcomes
451
Countries such as South Korea and Japan which placed significant emphasis early on FTTH are now clearly ahead of most (although not all) European countries as regards fast broadband as shown in section 1 above
(iii) The lack of incentives for incumbents to co-invest; experience has shown that this is relatively unlikely to happen in local markets, unless a credible threat of roll-out by competitors is present or where the incumbent has responded to a policy push.
(iv) Likewise in areas where no NGA infrastructure is present the emergence of new local operators may be discouraged by the commercial threat posed by existing operators that have (non NGA) infrastructure in place.
(v) Lack of sufficient measures to support NGA deployment by alternative investors. By focusing regulatory model on SMP finding, the system perpetuates a model built at a time where only one network was deployed. It fails to take account of other operators and investment models, which could benefit from greater support.
The implementation of basic competition safeguards which could help climb the ladder of investment (e.g., access to civil engineering of SMP operators) can be made difficult if access to civil engineering as a remedy is made ineffective by lack of information (mapping) or unclear or uncertain conditions 452 .
Further, while access regulation is a necessary condition for newcomers to enter the market, gain scale and ultimately replicate the network infrastructure, on the other hand regulated access at low prices has lower risks than full network build-out and thus may result in lower incentives for alternative operators to invest or co-invest.
Ubiquitous connectivity also requires efficient investment in the roll-out of very high quality networks fit for 5G technology, expected to drive business in the years to come. The architecture of 5G networks will be much denser than previous wireless networks (i.e. 3G and 4G) and thus a key challenge will be to adapt the licensing model accordingly, including by promoting licenseexempt spectrum or adaptations to the model of exclusive licensing. It has to be noted that in addition to spectrum needs the 5G deployment needs also substantial fixed assets at its disposal.
Poor auction design or renewals conditions and uncoordinated releases as well as timeframe between allocation and assignment of spectrum have severely hindered the level and the quality of the roll-out of 4G networks and this cannot be repeated. Rapid access to spectrum under appropriate conditions is key for early 5G network deployment.
6.10.2 Inefficient allocation mechanism for public funding
Investment needs remain considerable: as mentioned in annex 14, more than EUR 92 billion were needed in 2014 to bring our digital infrastructures up to the DAE 2020 broadband targets standard and more might be needed beyond that date to ensure that Europe's infrastructure remains competitive.
Where the market cannot deliver on its own, public funding can contribute to the wide deployment of VHC broadband networks. In particular the European Structural and Investment Funds (ESIF) the Connecting Europe Facility and the European Fund for Strategic Investment can help plugging the gap. These financing tools provide grants, financial instruments (equity, debt, guarantees) and can be cumulated to contribute funding a given project. While grants are mostly suited to plug gaps in market failure areas, financial instruments can reduce the risk profile in areas where a business case is present but remain underserved. However, one must be take into account that public support is a scarce resource and that it comes with significant constraints of legal, industrial and administrative nature; as an example OPEX is not included in grant funding, so the running costs fall on the network operator in any case.
452
However, in France and Spain, as well as in Portugal, duct access was ultimately pursued as the main remedy for NGA under the SMP regime. Duct access SMP conditions were set in 2009 in France and Spain and complemented with symmetric obligations for in-building wiring and in the French case, access to fibre terminating segments outside areas in which the NRA considered that infrastructure competition could develop. The positive impacts of this policy aredescribed in chapter 5.
However, the experience from the last programming period shows the trend that calls for tenders won by incumbents have typically resulted in copper enhancing solutions, while public support for VHC solutions has been more scarce.
The size of the tenders was also a problem, as it is very difficult for a new entrant to bid for large regions, while they might have a chance in smaller areas. Finally, the lack of a homogeneous network, infrastructure, investment and quality of service mapping by NRAs generates very different outcomes in terms of granularity of assessment and sometimes underestimates the amount of infrastructure present on the ground, diverting grants to area where a business case is possible. Also, the way the call for tenders are designed often ends up favouring the incumbent operator (size of the call, choice of direct support to operators instead of PPPs). The Commission is committed to make the most of the public funding leverage effect with a view to promote and unlock both public and private investment across Europe. This is all the more important as the public resources assigned to broadband infrastructure are limited, (EUR 6.4 billion for 2014- 2020 are devoted to broadband by Structural Funds) as explained in more details in Annex 14 (section 6.14.1)
The Commission and the MS should strive to work together to ensure a maximization of available resources for the financing of the broadband deployment including developing an appropriate funding mix between grants and financial instruments.
6.10.3 Fragmented regulated and commercial offers for businesses across the EU
Geographic market integration, leading to larger demand, more competition (allocative efficiency), lower costs (technical efficiency) and better product and services offers for customers (qualitative efficiency), is impeded by artificial barriers to the expansion of markets beyond borders. In the EU, the effects of various types of artificial barriers can be felt with regard to possibilities of access seekers to avail for consistently regulated access inputs, in particular with a view to serving business customers on cross-border basis, and with regard to non-harmonised end-user protection requirements.
Inconsistency of regulatory intervention in electronic communications markets, which acts as a barrier to market integration, is largely driven by three factors. First, national regulatory authorities have under the current regulatory framework not the appropriate incentives to opt for a DSM-compatible solution when choosing the appropriate regulatory remedy to a competition problem identified in a market. Indeed, NRAs exercise their discretion resulting in divergent approaches, for instance, in the regulation of fibre networks, symmetric regulation, pricing methodologies etc..
Although the current framework allows for flexibility in applying its general principles to national circumstances, this does not mean that all regulatory solutions can achieve the objectives of the framework or that they can all achieve them in the best way. Secondly, the technological complexity of networks, and in particular their local access parts, multiply this (inconsistency) problem by rendering the design of the technical details and requirements of comparable regulated access products more difficult. For example an international company purchasing communication services in different jurisdictions would not be able to receive a homogeneous offer on crucial elements such as activation or repair time. Thirdly, the current system does not allow identifying transnational demand nor as a consequence require NRAs to adopt remedies accordingly. This would enable the provision of connectivity for business users. Fourthly, the consistency check procedure (so called "Article 7 procedure") as well as the currently available "harmonisation procedures" (under Art.19 of the Framework Directive) would often not tackle the problem effectively, as such measures take too long to be implemented, leave too much room to national regulatory authorities to circumvent the outcome of the procedures and, thus, unnecessarily increase the lack of regulatory predictability.
Lack of consistency in regulatory responses to similar problems 453 does not just affect crossborder
operators, which have to adapt to different regulatory regimes and thus face greater internal market barriers. It also results in different levels of effectiveness of national regulatory regimes in fostering the best possible connectivity at affordable prices for end users. For example the implementation of VULA reference offers in different MS has resulted not only in different design outcomes, but also in different levels of take-up of this type of access products, which may be due to the attractiveness to access seekers in terms of quality. In other words, regulatory choices such as those regarding access obligations and the pricing of legacy networks have an impact on the investment decisions of operators. In this way, end users pay the consequences of inconsistent and potentially sub-optimal regulatory decisions, affecting retail markets.
6.10.4 Minimum harmonisation, differentiated rules
Over the past years, it has become apparent that the lack of consistency of telecoms regulation is – to a degree at least – the result of the institutional set-up and the way the various institutional players (i.e. mainly NRAs, BEREC and the EC) interact and can influence the regulatory outcome.
Whilst the EU Regulatory Framework had been designed with flexibility in mind in order to allow NRAs to take account of national circumstances, many differences in the national regulatory approaches cannot be sufficiently explained with varying national circumstances. This reasoning led to, for example, the Commission's recommendations in relation to costing methodologies ( termination rates and costing and non- discrimination recommendations). The inconsistency witnessed is exacerbated by the fact that the procedural and institutional set-up currently in place appears to be ill equipped to ensure a more consistent approach in similar circumstances.
For example, in the area of spectrum, while harmonization of technical conditions for spectrum use contribute to a great extent to the creation of economies of scale for device and network equipment manufacturers, the subsequent uncoordinated releases of spectrum to operators prevent these economies to be realized in full as network deployment only happens on a patchy manner, thereby increasing manufacturer´s development costs and the time to bring equipment to market. As investments decisions are increasingly made at global level, this phenomenon tends to discourage technology and equipment development in Europe to the advantage of other faster regions which will attract the investments.
Moreover, given that radio waves travel across national borders, the type of use of a frequency band in one MS has an impact on the type of use possible in neighbouring countries. In practice, if a MS uses a band for a specific type of application such as 5G before its neighbours who continue to emit with different technical parameters, interference problems could occur across
borders 454 – for example in bands below 1 GHz (i.e. 700MHz band). This problem would hence
be particularly relevant in smaller MS or in MS where a large proportion of the population lives within reach of signal transmissions from neighbouring countries. In addition, the very fact that there is only limited coordination of key determinants of market shaping inputs such as spectrum assignments across MS leads to more fragmented markets than necessary.
The current minimum harmonisation approach has also produced different outcomes and led to fragmentation in terms of consumer protection. In the field of contracts, for instance, this may be seen as a positive element, since NRAs can go beyond the minimum provisions of the Universal Service Directive where required. While the level of consumer protection - as measured by
453
In about 11% of all draft decisions subject to Art.7 notification the Commission has indicated that it may create a barrier to a single market or is contrary to EU law, or even if no formal decision has been issued by the Commission, the notifying NRA has withdrawn its notification.
454
Spectrum allocation and cross-sectoral interference issues fall out of the scope of this review. In particular, the work on managing interference between GSM (mobile) and GSM-R (mobile communications for railways) is addressed in serveral bodies ( CEPT and/or ERA) as well as at a national level. Some MS have introduced financing schemes to encourage the installation of filters and new radio modules in the railway cabin radios.
completeness of contracts, ease of comparing offers and extent of switching - is generally relatively high, the underlying measures are quite diverse. The diversity of national approaches creates a barrier to entry for pan-European operators active in multiple MS. The problem may be aggravated as MS may advance further and start developing their own measures in response to the previously identified problems.
6.10.5 Differentiated rules leading to uncertainty on spectrum assignment
Spectrum rules do not support optimal spectrum availability and deployment of mobile networks in Europe (regulatory failure).
The timely availability of spectrum to the single market, is negatively influenced by
(i) the time gap between spectrum allocation (harmonised use and technical conditions) and actual assignment to operators, (ii) the uncoordinated timing of assignment of same bands throughout MS and (iii) the varying conditions which govern spectrum renewal.
The current regulatory framework has no mechanism in place to facilitate a more consistent approach let alone to enforce it and most attempts to coordinate the assignment of spectrum has been made on a piecemeal, limited and insufficiently efficient approach with the need to adopt a specific legislative measure each time a deadline has to be set for the assignment of a part of the spectrum (the 2012 Radio Spectrum Policy Programme for 800 MHz 4G, the 1998 UMTS decision for 3G, the pending proposal for a EP and Council Decision on 700 MHz). Moreover, spectrum policy is often guided by national policy objectives which often do not take sufficient account of common EU policy objectives such as the promotion of high quality communications networks and the single market.
The figures below show for three major operators the timing and duration of licenses awarded. The diagram clearly indicates that, even where licenses were awarded in neighbouring countries, these awards took place in different years and they cover different durations.
Figure 75 - Example of differences in timing and duration of licenses for major EU operators
Source: Wik Consult
Furthermore, the existing spectrum governance structures focus on the harmonisation of technical parameters but may not allow for sufficient consistency of the timing of effective use of spectrum once allocated. Moreover, spectrum is assigned with varying conditions reflecting different (national) balances of the primary objectives underpinning the regulatory framework. This leads to disparate conditions where a national border bisects otherwise similar areas. The absence of consistent EU-wide objectives and criteria for spectrum assignment, as well as for changes to the conditions applicable to individual rights of use, at national level creates barriers to entry, hinders competition and reduces predictability for investors across Europe.
6.10.6 Technological and market changes
There have been significant changes in the telecommunications market since the last review that have affected the way in which end users communicate. The increasing coverage of wired and wireless broadband networks, coupled with the availability and affordability of consumer devices, have made consumers and businesses to rapidly adopt new communications services that rely on data and internet access services instead of traditional telephone services. The market has seen how in very few years new players have managed to compete with traditional telecom operators by offering a new set of communications applications over the internet.
Although there are still significant variations across Member States, overall European consumers have been very quick in adopting these new communications services. At the end of 2015, a significant number of citizens used instant messaging services, a relatively new service, several times per day compared to the users of e-mails or phone calls over a landline phone (30% vs. 27%). On average, 50% of Europeans use instant messaging services regularly, with 36% using them daily.
Figure 76 – Use of Instant Messaging in EU member States
Projections on future take-up of instant messaging simply confirm current trends. The volume of IP messaging, which was still negligible in 2010, exceeded the SMS volume only three years later and it is expected to further increase its predominant share of overall messaging traffic in the future. In 2014 alone instant messaging services on mobile phones would have carried more than twice the volume (50 billion versus 21 billion per day) of messages sent via a short messaging service (SMS).
With regards to revenues, it is estimated that between 2008 and 2014 fixed and mobile revenues declined in the EU by 19%. In both markets there has been a drop in traffic-related revenues. Taking into account also factors that are largely independent of the rise of OTT, such as revenue decrease due to regulatory intervention (by NRAs or by the EC, such as a decline in termination and roaming rates) or due to the global economic downturn, the study SMART 2013/0019 concludes that the rise of OTTs had no impact on fixed revenues, but did negatively impact mobile revenues.
Figure 77 - Mobile and Fixed revenues in the EU (million Euros)
As regards to the provision of wireless connectivity, the upcoming 5G technology revolution requires a fit for purpose spectrum management chain including allocation and assignment, since the way airwaves are regulated depends partly on the technologies used and services offered. Future users of dense 5G networks will need greater flexibility on both, access and use of spectrum but today, in the current framework, there are insufficient incentives for holders of rights to use spectrum efficiently in terms of technology and capacity.
There is consensus on the need to develop spectrum sharing to enable the 5G revolution. Today there is much focus in the use of individual often exclusive licenses (which are justified for some uses, e.g. mobile, to avoid interferences) but no sufficient incentives for secondary market for spectrum. In addition, it becomes clear that commercial operators are also using license exempt spectrum, notably for distributing Wi-Fi based connectivity from fixed infrastructures. Barriers to spectrum entry need to be lowered to stimulate innovation and new services.
6.10.7 Increasing adoption of bundles
In response to network convergence and increased competition, telecom operators have started to bundle different services like TV and Voice telephony to the internet access service. Moreover, given the convergence of fixed and mobile services, also mobile services (voice and data) are increasingly added to the bundle.
A bundle refers to a package of several different services sold together as a single plan: landline calling, Internet access, mobile services, pay-tv. In 2014 take up of broadband bundled products per total population was 46%, five points higher than the previous year, with an ever increasing number of triple and quadruple play products.
The growing take-up of bundled services can be seen in the figure below. Double play bundles are still most common, but triple and quadruple play bundles are gaining significance.
Figure 78 – Adoption of bundles in the EU, 2010-2014
At the end of 2015, 87% of households in the Netherlands and 78% in Malta had purchased bundles services, as had at least half of all households in 19 other Member States. Italy, the Czech Republic and in Lithuania were at the other end of the scale with 31%, 32% and 34% of households respectively. Since 2009 there has been an increase in the number of households subscribing to bundled products in all Member States, as shown in figure 68.
Figure 79 – Adoption of bundles per MS, 2009-2015
6.10.8 Suboptimal design of market review cycles and Inconsistent remedies under current rules (art.7)
This problem driver consists of insufficient legal certainty and regulatory predictability regarding access obligations on NGA networks due to short market review cycles, lack of sufficient focus on retail markets and the difficulty of enforcing consistency on the basis of nonbinding recommendations, impacting network roll-out.
Provisions therefore need adjustments with a view to reducing the regulatory burden and make regulation more clear and certain. The current process of frequent market reviews and ex ante regulation has been reported in certain MS to cause little regulatory predictability and legal certainty, on top of being rather cumbersome. This is related on the one hand to the variety of (unranked) goals and remedies available to NGAs, but also to the relatively short regulatory cycles (every three years, significantly shorter than investment cycle), in particular when considered together with the associated appeals and court procedures. While regulation needs to move along with a fast changing sector, operators often stress the need for regulatory predictability.
It is also worth noting that the short cycle of market reviews, the lack of predictability and the litigation that may follow have a discouraging effect on institutional investors such as infrastructure funds, private equity and pension funds that may be willing to invest capital in the sector's network operators, especially on a long-term horizon. On the other hand, investors attracted by short-term gains and price arbitrage may be more attracted by a more volatile environment. The effects of this "adverse selection" problem may hamper infrastructure deployment which has is definition a long-term asset class, especially for operators which are smaller and more exposed to instability.
Whilst market fragmentation is not solely to blame on the regulatory set-up in the EU, it has become apparent over the past years, that the lack of consistency of telecoms regulation is – to a degree at least – the result of the institutional set-up and the way the various institutional players (i.e. mainly the NRAs, BEREC and the Commission) interact and can influence the regulatory
outcome 455 .
Whilst the EU Regulatory Framework had been designed with flexibility in mind in order to allow NRAs to take account of national circumstances, the Commission has repeatedly pointed out that many differences in the national regulatory approaches cannot be sufficiently explained with varying national circumstances. The inconsistency witnessed is exacerbated by the fact that the procedural and institutional set-up currently in place appears to be ill equipped to ensure a
more consistent approach in similar circumstances 456 .
In particular increased consistency in market regulation and management of scarce resources would contribute greatly to a true Single Market. With regard to both areas, of course, there may
be various sub-themes 457 , which would benefit more broadly from an institutional set-up that
was geared more thoroughly towards ensuring consistency. Where the problem of inconsistency
455
See, for example, the EP study on " How to Build a Ubiquitous EU Digital Society ", p. 100 where it is stated that "[…] the fact that Heads of NRAs are considered primarily to be motivated by a desire for self-determination, has led to some criticisms that BEREC delivers verdicts based on a 'lowest common denominator', or prioritises flexibility over consistency in the Single Market."
456
In particular, with regards to imposing remedies, the balance between achieving harmonisation in a flexible framework appears to have been tilted in favour of flexibility neglecting legitimate needs for consistency. For example, whilst remedies are imposed on operators by NRAs at the national level, the Commission and BEREC almost exclusively input through non-binding instruments in order to attempt to achieve EU-wide regulatory consistency on this level. In the past, this "soft law" approach has led to significant differences in some areas, clearly proving to be an obstacle for the development of a Single Market.
457
For example, issues surrounding the independence and funding of NRAs, the constitutional set-up of BEREC, the design of the EU consolidation process under Article 7, the Commission's powers to adopt harmonisation measures under Article 19, standardisation, rights of way, numbering, spectrum management, naming and addressing to name but a few.
and fragmentation arises is exactly where the Commission does not have veto powers (and relies on the non-binding recommendations), i.e. on the remedy side.
First, concerning market regulation, one area, in relation to which a more consistent approach is particularly important, is the choice and design of access remedies. Unfortunately, it is especially in this area where there is the most notable divergence across the EU. Whilst competition still predominantly takes place at the national level, EU-wide consistency in designing access remedies is increasingly considered important.. In addition to access remedies, fragmentation of other regulatory conditions (e.g. authorisation conditions) may also represent an obstacle to
market entry and cross-border provision of services 458 .
6.10.9 Obsolete and redundant rules
A number of regulatory inefficiencies can be identified in the current regulatory setting, which are generating unnecessary compliance costs and discouraging investment. Given the technological and market changes described above, certain provisions of the framework might no longer be relevant or might have become superfluous.
This is the case for example for part of the Universal Service rules. The evolution of consumers' behaviour, the wide coverage and availability of mobile networks and services, and the provision by the market of comprehensive directories and directory enquiry services, which also experience strong competition from other (notably online) information sources, have eliminated or at least reduced the need for including certain universal service obligations, such as the phone directories and public pay telephones. These changes will require an adaptation of the Universal Service regime to remove outdated services. Moreover, with already nearly 100% standard fixed broadband coverage in the EU, universal service obligations regarding the availability of functional internet access and telephone service are likely to become redundant in many MS in the future.
Further provisions might have become superfluous due to legislative developments in other regulation areas. Some of the sector-specific consumer protection rules (e.g. Article 20 and 34 Universal Service Directive) are examples of provisions that need to be reviewed in those respects to avoid that overlapping rules contribute to the unnecessary administrative burden.
Overlaps in legal frameworks on consumer protection are just one of the issues to be addressed in this review. Sector-specific rules aimed at providing a particular level of protection to users of ECS in areas such as data protection, privacy and security, freedom of choice and prevention of lock-in effects, transparency, quality and affordability and access to emergency numbers. These rules only apply to providers of ECS.
While in some case these rules applicable to consumers can be complementary, there are may be
instances where overlaps between the different set of rules can occur 459 . For example the
information requirements in the Consumer Rights Directive overlap with certain general provisions of Article 20 Universal Service Directive, while Article 34 Universal Service Directive on out-of-court dispute resolution is covered by the Directive on alternative dispute resolution for consumer disputes.
A specific situation may fall within the scope of two Directives or within the scope of specific provisions of these directives and create a circular cross reference. One example may be the priority provisions in Article 1(4) USD "The provisions of this Directive concerning end-users’ rights shall apply without prejudice to Community rules on consumer protection, in particular Directive-s 93/13/EEC and 97/7/EC, and national rules in conformity with Community law" and Recital 11 of the CRD: “this Directive should be without prejudice to Union provisions relating to specific sectors, such as […] electronic communications”.
458
The negative impact a fragmentation of conditions has on the provision of connectivity services has been widely reported by the BEREC consultation on the cross-border obstacles to business services , and in the EP study on the assessment of the EU Regulatory Framework (p. 42 and 107).
459
See for a detailed analysis the SMART 2015/005
Another example is Art. 3 of ADR Directive, which states that "if any provision of this Directive conflicts with a provision laid down in another Union legal act and relating to out-of-court redress procedures initiated by a consumer against a trader, the provision of this Directive shall prevail”.
This overlap results in a complex legal framework, with different consequences: the risk that it is not fully respected; penalties could be contradictory within MS; differences in implementation may also be due to an inconsistency among terminology; and these problems are compounded to the prejudice of the internal market when rules are based on minimum harmonisation.
6.11 ANNEX 11 - 5G spectrum requirements for connected car (use case)
In the study on 'Identification and quantification of key socio-economic data to support strategic planning for the introduction of 5G' SMART 2014/0008 spectrum estimates within each subrange are calculated by multiplying the number of devices by their respective occupancy of the spectrum in bps according to the scenario and multiplied by the assumed spectral efficiency of the technology used for each device type.
The different approaches of 100 per cent sharing (fully shared) versus 0 per cent sharing (exclusive licensing) have a very high impact on the total demand to support either type of operation. In a fully shared (100 per cent sharing) environment, the spectrum needed is equal to the total use case driven demand estimate. In an exclusive licencing environment however, the spectrum needed is equal to the total use case driven demand estimate multiplied by the number of operators in the environment. This approach is taken to understand the minimum and maximum spectrum requirement figures.
In the connected car example illustrated below is based on two very high data rate use types within the transport and automotive verticals, once the theoretical total (user driven) demand estimates is calculated, the spectrum needs are analysed based on the five different spectrum sharing scenarios. In doing so, this use case is intended to drive the spectrum requirements to an extreme level to understand the impact on spectrum in a very challenging environment.
The table below shows how the total quantity of spectrum varies depending on the different sharing scenarios that may emerge by 2025.
Table 38 - Total spectrum requirements relative to percentage of spectrum sharing scenarios based on theoretical model
Spectrum sharing scenario Total spectrum needed (GHz)
Scenario 1: 0% sharing 56.1
Scenario 2: 20% sharing 47.7
Scenario 3: 50% sharing 35.1
Scenario 4: 75% sharing 24.5
Scenario 5: 100% sharing 14.0
The figure shows the total spectrum requirements for each scenario split by the quantity of dedicated and shared spectrum in each case.
Figure 80 - Total spectrum requirements for motorway use case
All -exclusive case requires the largest quantity of spectrum (56.1 GHz) because each individual of the four-service provider (x4) requires approximately the same amount of spectrum estimated for the given scenario. The all (100 per cent) shared case has the lowest spectrum requirement with a total of 14.0 GHz of spectrum. If by 2025 full sharing is not possible then a mix of dedicated and MNO sharing with the 5G use cases (connected car, eHealth, transport and utilities) helps to minimise the total quantity of required spectrum compared to the all dedicated case.
The option of sharing spectrum becomes a benefit to service providers as the proportion of shared spectrum increases. Total required spectrum reduces however, for each frequency range where there is a limit to the quantity of available spectrum in each range. Therefore, this result shows that some sharing will be necessary in Sub-1 GHz band because MNOs will likely only have access to no more than 75 per cent of the spectrum in this sub-range by 2025 and therefore sharing with other operators and new MVNOs will be required to serve the users in this transport scenario below 1 GHz.
6.12 ANNEX 12 – Comparison of impacts by stakeholders
In this annex, we present the summary tables of impacts on different groups of stakeholders in; they were compiled under the supporting study to this IA on the basis of the public consultation, the interviews with stakeholders and workshops organised by the EC. As mentioned in section 4.8 we pay specific attention to positive and negative impacts, direct and indirect on specific categories of stakeholders, including SMEs, as required by the SME test under the better regulation principles and public administrations. Although the impacts on stakeholders are addressed for all the options considered under each policy area, a wider attention is paid to the preferred option for each policy area. A more complete and narrative version is provided in SMART 2015/0005, chapters 1 to 5.
6.12.1 Access regulation
Table 39 - Summary stakeholder impacts – access options
Option 1: Status quo Option 2: Continuity and Option 3: Fibre-ready Option 4: Reduction in scope of simplification regulation
Consumers Mixed – some may be well-served As option 1 Substantial benefits arising from Negative – significant reductions in but existing gaps may remain higher broadband quality of competition could be expected service due to increased impacting pricing and service deployment and competition in quality, although some further very high speed broadband. Some investment might be made
market consolidation also possible, which may have positive as well as negative impacts on innovation and price
SMEs Mixed – some may be well-served As option 1 Substantial benefits arising from Negative – significant reductions in but existing gaps may remain higher broadband quality of competition could be expected service due to increased impacting pricing and service deployment and competition in quality, although some further very high speed broadband. investment might be made
Larger and Negative – fragmentation would As option 1 Benefits from greater fibre Highly negative – significant multi-national continue to impact cross-border availability (also reaching smaller reductions in competition and businesses connectivity sites, homeworkers) and consistent further cross-border fragmentation
wholesale specifications, if SMP approach maintained for business access
Incumbents Negative – existing regulatory Some benefits compared with Mixed. Some benefits – potential Highly positive – significant burden and constraints would status quo – more certainty, lifting of sectoral regulation, but reduction in regulatory burden and remain higher burden of proof for also tighter regulation of ducts, constraints and lessening of intervention, but may also pressure to invest competition
facilitate functional separation
Entrants Mixed – continuation of access Some benefits compared with Benefits for larger scale players Highly negative – may undermine
360 regulation positive, but no status quo – more certainty, able to invest and co-invest. business viability emphasis on supporting more greater potential for functional Negative for smaller entrants sustainable competition. Therefore, separation, but also higher relying on wholesale access practical application varies by burden of proof for intervention country. Entrants vulnerable to – may reduce regulation technological and regulatory change.
Alternative Neutral for existing players, but no As option 1 Positive – greater access to civil Neutral if not reliant on incumbent fibre investors additional support for further infrastructure, support for rural SLU/duct access. Otherwise
investment investments negative
Cable Stability considered highly positive, Benefits compared with status Mixed - Some benefits from Positive – reduced competition operators although continued wholesale price quo – more stability, higher potential lifting of wholesale price
regulation could undermine burden of proof for intervention regulation, but also greater revenues infrastructure competition and pressure to invest
Content and Mixed – existing bandwidth gaps As option 1 Positive – greater bandwidth Negative – likely to impede takeapplication would remain, but competition availability, but risk in some up of higher speed offers, and providers would continue to support take-up markets of consolidation impacting concentrate the market, raising risk
and protect vs discriminatory competitive safeguards of discriminatory conduct conduct
Equipment Neutral to negative – no specific Neutral to negative – no specific Mixed – depending on business Mixed – depending on business manufacturers stimulus for investment by industry stimulus for investment by model/customer-base model/customer-base
industry
NRAs Mostly positive – retain existing Positive – NRAs would benefit Mixed – NRAs would have more Negative – NRAs would lose an flexibility. But several NRAs have from continued flexibility, but prescriptive requirements. Those important tool for the promotion of raised concern over burden of 3 with reduced market analysis not already pursuing mapping competition, while potentially yearly review requirement + some administrative requirements and analysis and the operationalization facing an increased burden in NRAs raise concerns over increased potential to of duct access may require dispute resolution
independence and resourcing) implement functional additional resources to do so in the separation. Under this option short term – although the admin their resources and remit would
361 also be strengthened burden may reduce longer term
BEREC Neutral Positive – remit would be This option would entail the Highly negative. BEREC would expanded and NRAs‘ strengthening of BEREC lose a significant portion of its competences would be aligned Governance as well as additional current remit (concerning market with BEREC‘s responsibilities. Although analysis).
BEREC’s competence and influence would be expanded, NRAs would have less direct control over its Governance.
6.12.2 Spectrum
Table 40 - Summary stakeholder impacts – spectrum options
362 Option 1: Status quo Option 2: voluntary Option 3: binding Option 4: spectrum agency
End-users (consumers and Negative – late and Mixed – while this option Positive – this option Mixed – while this option business) uncoordinated deployment could be in place fast, there delivers a coordinated sets up a governance
of 5G and lack of action on is a high risk that voluntary approach to spectrum structure to address the recent 700 MHz auctions measures would not be assignment and usage across problem, the complexity of means businesses are taken-up by many MS, the EU including for 5G negotiating this set-up means unable to develop new leaving the same results as (though it may come too late it will come too late to services (e.g. in transport, under option 1 to influence 700 MHz influence 700 MHz auctions automotive, healthcare, assignments) and will delay 5G utilities etc.) and deployment consumers (including businesses) don‘t benefit from innovative services
SMEs Negative – the impacts Mixed – the impacts would Positive - the impacts would Mixed - the impacts would would not differ from those not differ from those for not differ from those of other not differ from those of other for other end-users other end-users end-users. Swift end-users. Swift implementation of 5G would implementation of 5G would create opportunities for create opportunities for innovation and innovation and entrepreneurship which entrepreneurship which would benefit SMEs in would benefit SMEs in particular. particular
General authorisations could provide greater opportunities for SMEs to gain access to spectrum which is now only accessible to large companies with the financial power to purchase exclusive rights (e.g. MNOs, etc.)
MNOs Negative – this option risks Mixed – while this option Positive – this option Mixed – while this option
363 repeating the 4G scenario could be in place fast, there delivers a coordinated sets up a governance where Europe lagged is a high risk that voluntary approach to spectrum structure to address the behind other regions for measures would not be assignment and usage across problem, the complexity of
5G with insufficient taken-up by many MS, the EU including for 5G negotiating might delay 5G investment leaving the same results as (though it may come too late deployment under option 1 to influence 700 MHz assignments)
Other spectrum users (e.g. Nil – this option would Nil - This option would Uncertain - This option Uncertain - This option broadcasters, PMSE, etc.) continue the current set-up likely not differ provides a greater level of provides the greatest level of
which engenders significantly from option 1 regulatory certainty and regulatory certainty – significant local variability, consistency across MS, impacts on other spectrum continued erosion of impacts on other spectrum users would depend on spectrum for some users users would depend on specific decisions taken by and uncertainty about specific decisions taken by the spectrum agency. There future spectrum availability but the peer review would be less scope for mechanism could ensure that adaptation to local needs local needs of different under this option. spectrum users continue to be fully taken into account.
Equipment manufacturers Negative – this option Negative – this option risks Positive – this option Positive – this option repeats the 4G scenario repeating the 4G scenario provides greater regulatory provides greater regulatory
(late & uncoordinated for 5G and therefore fails certainty and consistency to certainty and consistency to assignments) for 5G and to provide legal certainty manufacturers proving them manufacturers providing therefore fails to provide and it fails to capitalise on with incentives to invest now them with incentives to legal certainty and it fails the size of the Single in order to serve the Single invest now in order to serve to capitalise on the size of Market Market the Single Market the Single Market
364
6.12.3 USO options
Table 41 - Summary of impacts on stakeholders – universal service options
Option 1: Status quo Option 2: Light adjustment Option 3: Broadband Option 4: Broadband
(baseline) affordability availability
Consumers Risk of social exclusion and Risk of social exclusion and Connection of disadvantaged As option 3, especially for of the deepening digital of the deepening digital households, reduction of the rural and remote areas
divide, support of redundant divide risk of social exclusion, services access to advanced services
SMEs 0 0 Support of self-employment As option 3 and micro-organisation
Larger and multi-national 0 0 0 0 businesses
Incumbents 0 Alleviating the financial Alleviating the financial and As option 3; potentially burden by narrowing the administrative burden by increase or entrenchment of USO scope narrowing the scope and the market power
modernising the funding
Entrants Legal uncertainty with regard As option 1 More legal certainty with As option3; potentially to financing regard to financing increase or entrenchment of
incumbent’s market power; distortion of price levels; more difficult market entry
Alternative fibre investors 0 0 Alleviating the financial and As option 3; distortion of administrative burden competition and price levels;
365 crowding out investments
Cable operators 0 0 As above As above
Mobile/ wireless providers 0 0 Alleviating the financial and As option 3 administrative burden; more
equitable cost-benefit relation in the case affordable mobile broadband
Content and application 0 0 Improved channels for As option 3 providers advanced communications
services and greater audience
NRAs 0 Less flexibility in the Flexibility with regard to the As option 3 adjustment of the USO to national USO; no choice with
national circumstances regard to financing
366
6.12.4 Services options
Table 42 - Summary stakeholder impacts – services options.
Option 1: Status quo Option 2: Option 3: Option 4: Option 5:
-
A)Security and privacy issues remain. A) 0 A) More issues A) Fewer issues A) Fewer issues
-
B)Looming risk to lock-in with multi B) Lower risk B) Unclear (iii) B) Lower risk B) Lower risk
Consumers play bundles
-
C)As OTT usage increases, there is an C) 0
effective reduction of access to C) - C) + C) +
emergency numbers
-
D)0 D) ++ D) + D) ++ D) Unequal regulatory treatment vis-à-vis
OTTs remains.
Telco’s E) Compliance costs E) go down E) down less than in E) go down less E) same as 4 (i)
option 2 (i) than in option 3 (i)
-
F)duplication of costs when operating in
multiple countries F) market entry i.s.o. F) same as 2 F) down (ii)
regulatory barriers (iv) F) same as 2
OTTs G) no compliance cost except some legal cases as to the scope of the RF G) 0 G) reduced G) new compliance costs G1) New compliance costs
367 G2) regulatory risk (vii)
G3) impede
innovations(vii)
IoT Start-ups I) Low confidence in future planning and I) More clarity but more I) clarity about
and SMEs investments due to unclear scope of RF I) 0 market risks (v) scope I) clarity about scope
NRAs L) Enforcement costs K) 0 (i) K) go up (vi) K) 0 (i) K) go up (vii)
(i) Reduction in compliance costs due to cancelling redundant rules are significant. Reduction of enforcement costs by NRAs are zero. From option 2 to
3 the number of obligations for ECS reduce, but new obligations for ECN arise. From 2 to 4 and 5, the reduction in obligations for ECS remain the same, but the number of obligations for ECN go up. Additional measures that impact on OTTs do not impact on Telco’s
(ii) Streamlining reduces the dimensions for regulatory heterogeneity. While lack of clarity about the scope of the RF may lead to evolution of interpretations by MS and create new heterogeneity of rules, this would not affect Telco’s but rather OTTs and IoTs.
(iii) Measures to reduce lock-in with multi-play service providers may be offset by relaxing obligations for interconnection and subsequent concentration of the market.
(iv) Relaxing obligations to interconnect may allow for the creation of market entry barriers as National Markets concentrate.
(v) IoT start-ups will have less uncertainty about rights and obligations and experience less duplication of costs when operating in multiple countries, however, Option 3 may introduce competition issues for number-based m2m service providers vis-à-vis large telco’s.
(vi) Risk of more need for ex-post interventions in which NRAs may need to support CAs
(vii) Interconnection on the basis of “reasonable limitations of technical feasibility as well as cost limitations” gives rise to enforcement/implementation costs, uncertainty and risks for innovation
368
6.12.5 Must carry and EPG obligations
Table 43 ---Summary stakeholder impacts – Must carry and EPG obligations
Option 1: Status quo Option 2: Phase out obligations Option 3: Extend must carry obligations to OTT providers
Consumers Positive, viewers continue to have Negative, in some cases viewers Neutral compared to option 1: No impact on access to PSB services via traditional may lose access to PSB services PSBs (neither small or large) or on the variety of TV networks via traditional TV networks content offered to (i.e. choice for) end-uses. The before OTT substitution is viable abundance of online content could make it more difficult for some smaller PSBs to build a significant audience
Larger and multi-national Neutral – market entry might Positive - market entry could Neutral. No change in the possibilities to make commercial content continue to focus on the OTT area include traditional TV networks content available compared to status quo as OTT providers which has less regulatory constraints to the extent that transmission providers already include PSB content.
capacity becomes available subsequent to discontinuation of must carry obligations
PSBs, including at regional Positive, existing privileges would Negative, appropriate Negative as concepts for proportionate and and local level remain in place transmission on traditional TV appropriate intervention in the OTT area do not
networks would have to be currently exist. Positive effects are possible in negotiated under market the long terms, if such intervention can finally be conditions. successfully conceived.
ECNs Neutral/positive – existing regulatory Strongly positive - existing Neutral – no change of existing burdens and burdens and constraints would regulatory burdens and constraints
remain, but with a perspective that constraints would disappear by they will be removed gradually over 2020-2025 time subsequent to national reviews of obligations.
369
OTT service providers Neutral – existing obligations do not Neutral – existing obligations do Negative as concepts for proportionate and which are not themselves relate to OTTs not relate to OTTs appropriate intervention in the OTT area do not content providers currently exist.
6.12.6 Numbering options
Table 44 - Summary stakeholder impacts – Numbers.
Option 1: Status quo Option 2: Option 3:
Consumers A) Higher prices for Iot services A) same as option 1 A) Lower prices
-
B)Higher prices for Iot services B) same as option 1 D) Lower prices
-
C)Potential barriers for cross border use C) same as option 1 E) Less risk of applications
IoT users (Industry 4.0)
-
D)same as option 1 F) Less barriers D) Potential barrier for full integration into the IoT
-
E)Potential lock-in with connectivity E) same as option 1 E) Less risk
providers, leading to high prices and lower quality
IoT service providers (including SMEs) F) same as option 1 F) potential bottlenecks in delivering F) Less bottlenecks reliable always and everywhere connected services (domestic and cross border)
370 G) Less room for innovations of IoT G) same as option 1 G) More room for innovations services
-
H)High prices and profits H) same as option 1 H) lower prices, less profits
Telco’s I) growing administrative costs related to I) same as option 1 I) Lower administrative costs
extra-territorial use of numbers
-
J)growing administrative costs related to NRAs facilitating the extra-territorial use of J) same as option 1 J) Lower administrative costs
numbers
371
6.12.7 Governance
Table 45 - Costs of institutional options per stakeholder
Baseline (option Preferred options access and spectrum (option 3) and services (option 4) 1)
Bodies Status quo Enhanced advisory role Advisory role + some EU regulator with
(option 1) (option 2) normative powers (option 3) implementation/enforce ment powers (option 4)
Commission → ↑ (EU technical guidelines) ↑ Spectrum peer review ↑ Spectrum peer review
BEREC Agency → ↑ (Additional advisory ↑↑ (Enhanced technical ↑↑↑ (substantial additional requirements + compliance guidance role + compliance resourcing required)
with Common approach) with Common approach
NRAs → ↑↑ (effective resourcing, ↑↑ (effective resourcing, ↑ (additional contribution additional advisory additional contribution to to BEREC) ↓↓ Fewer contribution to BEREC, BEREC, mapping) ↓↓ Fewer market analyses, some mapping) ↓↓ Fewer market market analyses, standardised enforcement powers to EU analyses, standardised specifications
specifications
Spectrum → ↑ Increased contribution to ↑ Increased contribution to ↑ Increased contribution to authorities RSPG RSPG RSPG
↓ Greater EU guidance ↓ ↓ Some enforcement powers to EU
A more analytical estimation of the costs is presented in SMART 2015/0005.
372 Table 46 – Summary of governance costs by option
373
Option 1 Option 2 Option 3 Option 4
Synergy + some
Enhanced Synergy + some normative and
Body Status quo Assumptions advisory role Assumptions2 normative powers Assumptions3 supervision powers Assumptions4
Commission € 7.328.400 60FTE @€118,640pa € 7.921.600 Status quo + 5FTE to reflect € 7.921.600 Status quo + 5FTE for € 7.921.600 As option 3
(blended rate) + additional implementation spectrum article 7 process
€210,000 missions duties
BEREC Agency € 4.061.000 28FTE €137,714pa (= € 5.713.571 40FTE as opposed to 28FTE, € 8.467.857 60FTE as opposed to 28FTE, € 31.000.000 EBA cost
blended rate of assumptions as before assumptions as before
€107,714 + additional
est €30,000 pp
overheads to reflect
small scale) + €205,000
missions
NRAs (excl spectrum) € 107.309.530 41FTE per NRA, blended € 103.103.146 Status quo + 5*10FTE for € 104.037.898 As option 2, but with € 90.951.370 As option 3 but with
cost for FTE €66,768pa, under-resourced NRAs + 10FTE additional contribution to reduction of 5FTE per
40% mark-up for for extra BEREC contribution. BEREC. NRA due to greater EU
overheads Cost savings on extended level rule-making and
market review periods (est supervision
15%). Cost increase associated
with mapping assumed
balanced by cost reductions
through standardisation +
reduced regulatory burden
(of which BEREC € 4.580.285 49FTE based on BEREC € 5.515.037 status quo +10FTE reflecting € 6.449.789 Status quo + 20FTE reflecting € 6.449.789 As option 3
contribution excl estimate four additional guidance additional contributions to
spectrum) requirements per year draft Implementing guidelines
RSPG support/office € 556.600 Based on 2.5 Cion FTE + € 556.600 Status quo € 556.600 Status quo € 0 Spectrum activities
€260,000 expenses incorporated within
BEREC
SMA € 83.753.779 32FTE per SMA blended € 83.886.802 Status quo + increased RSPG € 81.269.496 Option 2 with saving of 1 FTE € 73.417.579 As option 3 but with
cost €66,768pa, 40% contribution (see below) per SMA due to more further reduction of 3FTE
mark-up standardised auction format per SMA due to greater
EU level rule-making and
supervision (SMA in NRA)
(of which contribution € 266.045 Based on 14 WG mtgs € 399.067 Status quo +50% to reflect € 399.067 As option 2 € 399.067 As option 2
to RSPG) per year, 10 participants increased advisory
and 5 days prep requirements
€ 203.009.309 € 201.181.719 € 202.253.451 € 203.290.549
Total costs with
synergies (best case)
Total costs (EU co€ 16.792.330 € 20.105.875 € 23.794.913 € 45.770.456
ordination)
Co-ordination as % 8% 10% 12% 23%
total cost
Total costs (no € 203.009.309 € 210.996.615 € 214.685.652 € 234.043.890
synergies)
Total costs (average) € 203.009.309 € 206.089.167 € 208.469.552 € 218.667.219
374
6.13 ANNEX 13 - Report from the Expert Group meeting
On 30 May 2016, WIK-Consult GmbH, Ecorys Brussels N.V. and VVA Europe organised a high-level academic expert panel to support the Commission in the preparation of the Impact
Assessment for the Review of the electronic communications framework.
The purpose of the expert panel was to provide feedback on the provisional conclusions reached by the consultants concerning the impact of planned changes to the e-communications framework. Prior to the meeting, the experts were provided with a programme for discussion, slide presentation and draft ‘overview’ of the consultant’s research findings.
This Annex presents details on participating experts, the agenda of the day with points for discussion, and the report as reviewed by the members of the expert group.
PARTICIPATING EXPERTS:
The members of the academic panel were selected in consultation with the Commission by virtue of their in-depth experience in issues relevant to the electronic communications sector, innovation and governance.
Joan Calzada is Associate Professor at the Department of Political Economy, Universitat de Barcelona, with expertise in theoretical and empirical industrial organization. His main research interests are the economic regulation of network industries, especially telecommunications, transportation, and water.
Brett Frischmann is Professor and co-Director of the Intellectual Property and Information Law program at Cardozo Law School in New York City. His expertise lies in intellectual property and Internet law, and in particular the relationships between infrastructural resources, property rights, commons, and spillovers. Professor Frischmann is a prolific author, whose articles have appeared in numerous leading academic journals. He has published important books, including the award winning ‘Infrastructure: The Social Value of Shared Resources’ (Oxford University
Press, 2012).
Frederic Jenny is Professor of Economics at ESSEC Business School in Paris and a Chairman of the OECD Competition Committee. He has written extensively about trade, competition and economic development and his research areas concern the relationship between structure and performance in European countries and antitrust legislation in Europe.
Eli Noam is Professor of Economics and Finance at the Columbia Business School. His research focuses on strategy, management, and policy issues in telecommunications, computing, and electronic mass media. Noam has written numerous articles and books on subjects such as communications, information, public choice, public finance, and general regulation.
Dr Brigitte Preissl is Head of Knowledge Transfer in Economics at the German National Library of Economics in Hamburg. She has an extensive research record in the regulation of telecommunication markets, the economics of service innovation and national research systems.
Luc Soete is Professor of International Economic Relations at the School of Business and Economics, Maastricht University. His research covers a broad multi-disciplinary field which focuses on the nature, origin and determinants of innovation. Soete’s publications include topics on governance and institutions, ICT-enabled innovation as well as societal transformation.
Reza Tadayoni is Associate Professor at the Faculty of Engineering and Science, Aalborg University. His research field is media convergence. He has been contributed to a number of consultancy reports and studies for the Danish telecom and broadcast administration, EU and the
World Bank. He has been actively involved in European COST networks, including COST A20 on `The impact of the Internet on the mass media in Europe' and COST A16 on `ICT and transnational communities'.
Professor William Webb is a Director at Webb Search Consulting and an expert on wireless technology and regulatory matters. As a former director of Ofcom, he performed a research across all areas of Ofcom’s regulatory remit and led major reviews conducted by Ofcom including the Spectrum Framework Review, the development of Spectrum Usage Rights and most recently cognitive or white space policy.
The expert panel was introduced by Anthony Whelan, Director for Electronic Communications at the EC, DG Connect, and Chaired by Dr Iris Henseler-Unger, Managing Director of WIK.
Each subject was briefly introduced by a member of the study team on the basis of the circulated slides. Pertinent questions were raised by the Chair, and the remainder of the session was devoted to comments from experts.
AGENDA: EXPERT PANEL
IMPACT ASSESSMENT FOR THE REVIEW OF THE FRAMEWORK FOR ELECTRONIC COMMUNICATIONS
30 May 2016
Berlaymont, Room 07/062, Rondpoint Schumann, Brussels
The EC is currently undertaking a review of the legislative framework applying to electronic communications. The impact of the review could be significant. Electronic communications is a strategic sector which directly constitutes €168.62bln of European value added and 1.06 million jobs (around 1.3% GDP and 0.47% of total employment in 2012), with a labour productivity per person of more than 144 thousand euros (the highest rate within the ICT sector)1. The sector supports a wide range of other high-tech manufacturing and digital services (the ICT sector constitutes 4% GDP and 2.76% of EU jobs, with a labour productivity rate 44.45% higher than total labour productivity) as well as the economy as a whole.
The review comes at a crucial time for the digital economy. Consumer and business demand for bandwidth continues to expand, driven by the growth of connected devices, digital content services and cloud computing, as well as connected ‚things‘, we are mid-way through an important cycle of investment in fixed infrastructure with the prospect of 5G to come, and business models in the telecom sector are changing to adapt to a con-verged, data-driven environment.
These developments highlight a new ambition for ubiquitous and Very High Capacity connectivity. At the same time, they have revealed shortcomings in the framework, highlighting the need for the Framework to be adapted to meet market and technological change in order to protect consumer interests and enable competition to flourish across the single market.
Finally the review provides an opportunity to achieve efficiencies and see whether the complex processes and institutional framework in place today can be streamlined to reduce costs and bureaucracy.
In order to ensure that the changes to the framework are fit-for-purpose, in according the Better Regulation Guidelines, the Commission is conducting an Impact Assessment to gauge the economic, social and environmental effects of different options and assess how effective and efficient they would be in achieving the objectives we have identified above. The Commission has engaged WIK-Consult, Ecorys and VVA Europe to support them in this exercise. The purpose of the expert panel is to provide feedback on the provisional conclusions reached by the consultants concerning the impact of planned changes to the e-communications framework. Details of the programme are shown overleaf.
Programme Participants
Experts: Prof. Joan Calzada, Dr. Frédéric Jenny, Prof. Brigitte Preissl Prof. Luc Soete Prof. Reza Tadayoni Prof. William Webb, Prof. Brett Frischmann, Prof. Eli Noam
Commission Anthony Whelan, Reinald Krueger, Vesa Terava
Consultants Dr Iris Henseler-Unger, Ilsa Godlovitch (WIK), Nicolai van Gorp (Ecorys), Pierre Hausemer (VVA), Iglika Vassileva (Ecorys), Tseveen Gantumur (WIK)
Format Roundtable. The session is introduced by Anthony Whelan, Director for Electronic Communications at the EC, DG Connect, and Chaired by Dr Iris Henseler-Unger, Managing Director of WIK. Each subject is briefly introduced by a member of the study team on the basis of the circulated slides. Pertinent questions are raised by the Chair, and the remainder of the session is devoted to comments from experts.
Record Minutes will be taken of the panel proceedings and circulated following the workshop for comment and approval. The approved workshop minutes will be annexed to the final report under preparation by WIK, Ecorys and VVA.
09.30-10.00 Morning Coffee
10.00-10.30 Introduction and problem definition
Anthony Whelan EC
The context for the review Identifying the core problems: Gaps in high speed broadband deployment Delays in LTE roll-out, perspective for 5G The impact of market and technological developments Redundant regulation What should we seek to achieve?
10.30-12.40 Achieving ubiquitous high speed connectivity
Introduction by study team, debate
Approaches to access regulation to foster high speed broadband in urban and rural areas
Approaches to spectrum policy to accelerate deployment
12.40-13.40 Lunch
13.40-14.40 Protecting consumers and promoting competition and innovation in the single market
Introduction by study team, debate Approaches to services policy Need to adapt the concept of ‘electronic communications services’?
Relevance of the use of public resources (e.g. numbering resources) for sector-specific rights and obligations?
Which rules should apply to which communications services?
The role of universal service in securing access to connectivity
14.40-15.00 Break
15.00-16.00 Implications for institutional governance, jobs and growth
Introduction by study team, debate
Implications for institutional balance, role of NRAs, EC, BEREC and RSPG
How will achieving the objectives impact jobs and growth?
16.00-16.20 Concluding remarks and next steps
Anthony Whelan, EC
Draft report
The report included below needs approval by the expert group, which will be granted by the end of June 2016.
Access
The connectivity The experts agreed concerning the need to foster better infrastructure in rural areas,
imperative is not an where a potential digital divide still looms. There was some discussion over what
immediate short term the review of the framework should aim towards as regards objectives for connectivity overall and whether or not there should be an emphasis on very high
problem (except in speeds potentially delivered via fibre connections. One view was expressed that
rural areas)… FTTH may not be necessary to fulfil many of today’s domestic needs; even when
considering multiscreen 4K TV content, copper is also able to realise sufficient speeds. Moreover, the maximum capacity of In-house Wi-Fi may act as a bottleneck, limiting the effectiveness of Very High speed Connectivity (VHC)
unless this additional performance barrier is addressed. It follows that, from a short term perspective, the added value of VHC may not be so high in the eyes of consumers and this gives rise to uncertainty as to whether they would be willing to pay more for it. The impact of different technological solutions on cost and price should also be analysed.
…but it is a problem in It was agreed that this short term perspective should be taken into consideration. a forward looking However, some experts noted that the Framework should have a more forward perspective and the looking perspective. Market demand for VHC may not be there today, but you still
Framework should be might want to have infrastructures in place so that the market can evolve. In this
forward looking and sense, one could say there are market failures related to connectivity in the form of
supportive of externalities and spill overs (innovations) that are not incorporated in the current
innovation. willingness to pay by consumers. As such, VHC is a legitimate objective in a forward looking perspective but probably it will not be feasible to roll out FTTH re
all the way up to the homes across the entire Union by 2025; e.g. in some areas it may already suffice to roll out fibre to the lamppost (in order to operationalise 5G). However, when considering Europe's global competitiveness vis-à-vis other parts of the world, we may want to set even higher targets as it may not be enough to ‘catch up’ but rather to aim to ‘leapfrog’.
Solutions might not The experts noted the need to be clear about what were the market failures involved always be regulatory in the new context and highlighted that there may also be other market failures and may have to involved than market power, such as innovation externalities, resulting in social
involve public support demand for infrastructure not being reflected in current private demand. It follows
that regulatory tools to promote competition may not be sufficient and that public investments (eg by municipalities or via state aid) may be needed to complement regulatory tools. Other solutions discussed included as initiatives for aggregating local demand (as in Sweden) and/or to enable the cost of the (network) connection to be defrayed over a longer period than the current contract duration (24 month) while maintaining the current rules for contract duration for service contractst
Mapping is The experts indicated that the impact assessment should clearly specify where
considered an infrastructure competition alone does not work to stimulate connectivity and
important initiative. choice, and where accordingly additional solutions are needed. One important
the role of sunk costs market failure is the presence of sunk costs giving rise to economies of scale and market power. Regions differ in the scalability of investments and this problem
in different areas may be more pressing in white areas than in black areas. However, black areas may
can be considered a experience other sources of market failure. Mapping is therefore important to
market failure clearly describe the size of these problems: what is the magnitude of white areas? What are the potential problems in black areas? What are options to improve existing infrastructure? What is the interaction between electronic communication framework and state aid framework in these different settings?
With respect to the proposal to standardize of wholesale products for business communications, one of the experts questioned whether product innovation may be negatively impacted as a result of harmonization of specifications. However, it was
The trade-off noted that the wholesale products such as bitstream were often the result of
between regulatory intervention from the NRA to mandate access, and therefore such harmonization/stan products may be less likely to be subject to commercial innovation.
dardisation and
regulatory/commerc On the other hand, one of the experts noted that market failures may result from
ial innovation should a lack of harmonization. An analogy was made that once national networks have formed (e.g. in the banking sector) which largely serve national demand, none of
be considered them will spontaneously embrace pan-EU network solutions that serve
transnational demand but that may have some short-term costs. This
argumentation would call for more harmonization and the consideration of
options which are more radical such as moving to EU regulators.
Spectrum
Agreement on the
preferred option There was broad agreement among the experts that the spectrum analysis indeed shows that the preferred option would constitute a significant improvement over the status quo.
Several comments were made for the research team to consider in the final report. First of all, the experts agreed that the successful, fast and joint deployment of 5G is the key opportunity to be seized and the key challenge for
Need a definition of spectrum policy to tackle. While it is not yet clear precisely what 5G actually 5G entails, the experts suggested that an attempt should be made in the report to
define what is meant by 5G and to identify its key components (i.e. securing pioneer 5G bands) that will generate the impacts that are described in the impact assessment. Not all aspects of 5G technology will materialize at the same time: some aspects such as e.g. mmWave technology are currently still very much “research projects” that are likely to generate impact only in the longer term. At the same time, other aspects, such as enhanced mobile broadband are likely to be available much earlier.
Facilitating scaling Second, the experts agreed with the research team that the analysis should
up is one of the key clearly highlight how scale (and the speed of scaling up) is becoming an ever
impacts to consider more important imperative for economic operators, especially in network industries. The experts pointed out that a true digital single market across the
EU, for which spectrum is an important input, is a key element to facilitate such scaling up in Europe, experts mentioned 862-870MHz that is particularly suitable for IoT applications. It is such scale economies that lead investors (e.g. device manufacturers) to consider Europe as a significant player on the global stage, in comparison with other large markets such as the US or China. For instance, device manufacturers need to consider which spectrum bands their technology should be able to operate in. For Europe to ensure that it drives such decisions, it needs to present itself as a single market that is as economically attractive as other major markets.
Third, the panel discussed the difference between market structuring and public policy elements of spectrum assignments which should be acknowledged in the report. Market structuring elements include e.g. license duration, spectrum caps and other such elements. Public policy aspects refer to issues such as coverage obligations. It was noted that EU level intervention is likely to be most valuable
Distinguish between in the coordination of market structuring aspects, and in higher level framing of
market structuring overall policy objectives.
and policy aspects of
Option 3 should be a Lastly, it was generally acknowledged that the preferred option would make a
assignments
stepping stone to a significant difference in terms of coordinating spectrum assignments in Europe.
future more For the experts, the more far reaching Option 4 (an EU regulator) which is likely
ambitious move to lead to the biggest economic gains, is at the same time possibly less agile and
toward a more efficient in adapting to local constraints and likely to meet opposition from Member States . A suggestion was made that the impact assessment should be
consistent used to show the cost of such opposition by Member States (i.e. the difference in
management of impact between Option 4 and Option 3). There was consensus that Option 3
spectrum and could eventually be seen as a stepping stone to a future gradual move towards a possibly an EU sustainable and more consistent management of spectrum in the EU, and
regulator possibly to the creation of an EU regulator.
Services
Is numbering a It was noted that the description of the preferred option should more clearly specify
practical that the reference to "numbers" means E.164 numbers and no other numbering
distinguishing resources such as IPV6 addresses. Furthermore, it may need to be further analysed
feature? whether making use of numbering resources is a relevant distinguishing feature for applying sectorial obligations to services and whether this distinction is practically
applicable, although they did not elaborate on this point.
Regulatory Some experts noted that the analysis on regulatory heterogeneity and on the
heterogeneity is not impacts from harmonisation focuses on the gains of harmonisation but not so much
a bad thing per se on the possible costs for consumers. They agreed that regulatory heterogeneity with
regards to consumer protection leads to duplication costs, but questioned whether there are benefits to regulatory heterogeneity if consumer preferences differ. At the same time they agreed that certainty will be needed for the development of the M2M market. They agreed on the need to be transparent about the pros and cons of harmonisation.
What exactly do the Questions were raised as to what exactly the option with regards to bundles
measures with entailed. There were some doubts about the effectiveness and practicality of
regards to bundles offering consumers the ability to buy services separately. The issue is rather about
entail? the need to be clear on which rules apply to what services when a bundle contains services that fall within the scope of the regulatory framework and services that do
not. Once this is solved one should look at how services should be provided and what protections are needed. Consequently there is a need for some reasoning as to how sector specific rules apply to the bundle.
While consumers Some experts recognised that bundling may create transparency problems as
may clearly benefit consumers may find it more difficult to compare bundles to stand-alone products.
from bundling, there They noted that it is not always clear what is in the fine print and, in the end, a
are also risks consumer may have chosen a product in which he/she is actually not better off and it is not clear what the costs of getting out of the bundle are. Another potential
involved
concern, due to the popularity of bundles among end-users, was that some operators may be hindered in replicating bundles because they do not have access to relevant wholesale products (e.g. in Spain some operators have trouble getting wholesale access to mobile). However, other experts stressed that bundles may have positive attributes, not least to promote competition, and are no longer considered negative for consumers. Consumers also gain from bundles in the form of reduced transaction cost and a reduction of occasions at which a choice has to be made (consumers don’t like to make choices). Thus there is a need to go case by case rather than taking a single approach on this area and improve transparency through comparison tools.
.
The RF may not be One expert noted that the basis for extending privacy and security obligations to a
the right framework wider set of communication services is not strong if it is only based on the
for dealing with observation that one third of respondents to a survey find it an issue (referring to a survey held in the context of SMART 2013/0019). Another expert recognised that
privacy and security privacy and security issues are important in relation to communication services
issues (notably IoT services), but argued that the problem also applies to other types of
OTTs and not just to OTTs providing communications services. He suggested that in the future IPv6 addresses will replace E.164 numbers and that privacy and security issues should be dealt with under horizontal rules.
Universal service
Flexibility of While acknowledging the benefits of allowing Member States flexibility, experts
regulation at the were interested to understand how a universal service (US) obligation for basic
national level broadband would be defined if included, e.g. who determines what is the minimum bandwidth that should be guaranteed. They also inquired about the appropriateness
of including mobile connection in the options in this day and age where mobile technologies are becoming much more important. It was explained that there is minimum harmonisation at the EU level so that Member states have options to define their understanding of US pursuant to the national circumstances (e.g. with regards to a minimum required bandwidth) and that mobile technologies are currently included as a technology that can potentially be used to realise broadband services at a fixed location. However, nomadic services as such are not currently included as a US.
Underline the Experts noted that the problem analysis could make a clearer distinction between
distinction between affordability and availability. While the preferred option aims at affordability (e.g.
the measures for ensuring affordable prices for all end users, in particular for the most vulnerable), it
affordability and was argued that availability is the real issue to be considered by the RF in general,
availability of including possibly by US. Affordability can be realized through social income
broadband related policies or subsidies. It was explained that under the preferred option broadband availability would be further promoted through other instruments (such
as regulation, state aid or spectrum policy).
Differences between The analysis refers to “uncertainty” resulting from the fact that Member States have Member States may their own approach to assessing costs and unfair burden. It was questioned whether create complexity, but this causes “uncertainty”, or just “complexity”? It was explained that differences
not necessarily create between Member States in the calculation of net cost and the notion of unfair
uncertainty burden makes it not always clear to operators entering the market what will be the net cost of US provision, whether it will be considered an unfair burden and
whether they get any compensation, which may result in an uncertain market entry.
Governance
Centralisation is
important for scaling
On the topic of governance, the expert panel reaffirmed some of the policy specific elements discussed on access, spectrum and services. There was agreement that localised governance may prevent cross-border markets from emerging. If this is the case, then it significantly strengthens the case for co-ordination at EU level
Administrative costs Second, the experts pointed out that in estimating the costs of governance
related to a particular reform, it should be borne in mind that institutional costs are sticky and that
set-up might not be any savings from reform (e.g. administrative costs) might take a long time
easily reduced to materialize. One expert observed that institutions often end up maintaining the problem they were created to solve.
Subsidiarity needs to Third, one panel member challenged the team to consider subsidiarity in a be considered in light different light (finding the most appropriate geographic level of of the benefits of intervention rather than one that necessarily places responsibility at the
greater coordination most local level). He posited that, in the context of a digital single market,
there is a need to justify why a centralized, coordinated model of governance for electronic communications is not the right way forward. The European Research Cooperation (ERC) is an example where centralisation of the allocation of research grants has resulted in a much more efficient allocation of national research funds across EU researchers and also a more effective search for talent, since there are strong arguments for a larger scale when trying to identify high level expertise. It is a prime example of how the subsidiarity arguments (scale economies and spillovers) are at play and where centralisation leads to more efficient outcomes. A similar centralized model of governance could be beneficial in the case of e.g. spectrum.
The institutional set Finally, one panel member suggested that it is important to understand how
up needs to be open the governance model facilitates (rather than acts as a block to) innovation.
to innovation How can innovation (technological or regulatory) be introduced under a
new institutional set-up, what are the key steps for new ideas to be introduced, for their merits to be considered, for them to be decided and then implemented and how open is this process. For example one of the benefits the preferred spectrum option is that it is open to this idea discovery process but puts in fewer blocking factors than other options.
Macroeconomic modelling
The existing CGE analysis is a welcomed and well developed addition given the
The analysis reflects necessity to estimate future impact scenarios in a strongly quantitative way. But
existing production there are some limitations derived from the deterministic inclination of these functions but not models that should be noted.
disruptive changes of
production processes The model is based on current productivity parameters, while structural changes might be expected as a result of the implementation of the preferred policy options
together with a variety of factors. It should be noted that, ideally, the impacts should be analysed from a dynamic perspective, estimating the impact of changes in productivity as a result of both infrastructural and socio-economic factors, including organizational changes. This would require, among other things, that the analysis does not focus only on the horizontal comparison of industries, but also on the specifics of the production process throughout value chains and at the firm level. It is really important to understand how processes of production will change
Impacts may if policy strategies are to be rightly implemented.
materialize with a lag The analysis should account for the fact that it takes time to adopt changes,
implement them and, finally, for them to have impact on the production process. Moreover, the analysis should recognize limits in the absorptive capacity of firms.
Not all firms are instantly ready to jump to another production function. This has nothing to do with regulation, but with the potential to harvest the benefits of digitalization by industries. Such potential follows from the strategies that different industries and organizations might adopt e.g. regarding cloud computing. The consultants confirmed that such lags have been accounted for in the model.
CGE modelling is The CGE model seems to assume that the European economy is operating
limited in assessing independently of what happens in the rest of the world. While the current policy
the impact on options take the broadband situation in the most innovative economies as a
comparative benchmark, we have to go beyond that and have a vision to be more innovative
advantages vis-à-vis than others. For example, the model suggests that exports growth will exceed that
the ROW of imports. If you want to keep comparative advantage or achieve it, then you have to go beyond the benchmark of access policy, spectrum policy and service policy. It
was recognized that this is a general but accepted shortcoming of CGE modelling.
Regional models: It would be interesting to see a disaggregated model at regional level, similar to the
potentially very RHOMOLO model for example. Such models allow for analysing what would
promising but not happen on the ground in different industrial hubs around Europe. It is recognised
achievable under the that such models are indeed very interesting but also require an extensive amount
current IA of resources and development time when done properly.
Materializing of Finally, the experts note that the Regulatory Framework alone would not be enough impacts depends on to realise the preferred outcomes in terms of competitiveness of the EU economy. complementary Infrastructure policies should be complemented with innovation policies and policy
policies in the area of of digital services (in broader sense than just communication services). All these
innovation and digital different policy fields should go together.
services
6.14 ANNEX 14 – The state of play and the EU dimension of connectivity
This annex integrates the problem definition section by describing in more detail (i) the obstacles to unconstrained connectivity identified in section 1.2.1., (ii) the EU dimension of the problem and (iii) including more elements of the baseline, to complement the ones included in section
1.5.
6.14.1 Costing the gap and the financial endowment of current initiatives
Some studies have tried to estimate the NGA broadband gap in Europe and to provide estimates about the cost to fill it. The best known of these studies is probably the one performed by the
European Investment Bank in 2011. The study considers four scenarios for broadband deployment in Europe. The most ambitious scenario foresees FTTH/B roll-out throughout
Europe and the gap was estimated at €221 billion 460 . The same scenario of 100% FTTH/B coverage was analysed by Analysis Mason in a study for DG CONNECT in 2012 461 . The
amount foreseen is similar (€250 billion, for deployment of FTTP-only, across Europe). The amount is reduced to €154 billion in case of high duct re-use. Analysis Mason also estimated the costs associated to a 100% FTTC deployment which are in the area of €50 billion. In case of high duct re-use, the cost would go down to €31 billion.
An internal estimate on the basis of the Analysis Mason study was also carried out by DG CONNECT in 2014 according to which Europe needed an additional EUR 34 billion in investment to reach the target of 100% coverage at 30 Mbps, and an additional EUR 92 billion to credibly enable reaching the 50% take-up target at 100 Mbps 462 . These figures are already taking account of the amount that the private sector could be expected to invest 463 . and would leave part of the network unfit to serve a Gigabit society if substantial copper-based parts of the networks were to be durably maintained thereafter.
The financial resources available at the European level are certainly not sufficient to meet the challenge presented above. The allocation of European Structural and Investment Funds for high speed broadband networks experienced a sharp increase from EUR 2.7 billion in 2007-2013 to around EUR 6.4 billion for 2014-2020 (about EUR 5 billion ERDF and an estimated EUR 1.4 billion EAFRD) 464 . However, most of this investment is expected to be made in the form of grants rather than financial instruments so the leverage effect on public (national and/or regional co-funding) and private co-funding will not reach more than EUR 9-10 billion – falling far short from the needs to reach the EU targets for broadband coverage and take-up.
The Connecting Europe Facility (CEF) in the digital area is endowed with a limited budget of EUR 1 billion for the period 2014-2020 after the severe cuts it suffered in the Multiannual
Financial Framework (MFF) negotiations from a proposed EUR 9.2 billion. EUR 150 million are allocated to broadband infrastructure, based on the provision of financial instruments via the
460 http://www.eib.europa.eu/attachments/efs/eibpapers/eibpapers_2011_v16_n02_en.pdf
461
Analysis Mason, The socio-economic impact of bandwidth (2013).
462
Based on a 75% coverage assumption.
463
According to the Digital Agenda Scoreboard, telecom (including fixed, integrated and mobile-only) CAPEX in Europe was € 43 bn in 2013. CAPEX figures remained relatively stable over the 2011-2014 years despite the fact that in the same period NGA coverage increased from 29% to 68%. In 2014, Mobile CAPEX spending represented 59% of total spending. However, this CAPEX is not only directed at modernising the network so that it is difficult to say how much private operators will invest in increasing coverage in the coming years.
464 An estimate as the Commission cannot differentiate between allocations foreseen in EAFRD for ICT and
Broadband as this type of information is not requested by the regulation. However, additional information is requested and will be provided in the context of monitoring activities (in particular, monitoring will be done for ''N° of operations", "Population benefiting from new or improved IT infrastructure" differentiating here between "Broadband" and "Other than broadband").
European Investment Bank (EIB). The broadband part of CEF is expected to mobilise around
EUR 1 billion 465 .
Finally, the European Fund for Strategic Investment (EFSI) does not have sectorial earmarking hence it is difficult to anticipate how much budget will be allocated to broadband infrastrcuture.
6.14.2 International comparisons
Affordable Gigabit connectivity has already been available as a consumer service in Japan, 466
Singapore and Korea for some years, while in 2014 Korea’s SK Telecom announced trials of
10Gbit/s. 467 In Korea, the National Broadband Plan (Ultra Broadband Convergence Network 468 ),
already launched a 1 Gbps target in 2010.
Gigabit connectivity is also available to households and small businesses in US cities served by Google Fibre, 469 and recent reports suggest that AT&T is responding to the competitive challenge with more widespread urban Gigabit deployments of its own. 470 However, it is certainly not the case that all European countries are falling behind in a Gigabit society. As shown in the analysis carried out in SMART 2015/0002, Sweden or Estonia already today compare well with Japan on a range of NGA metrics (although Swedish fixed rural coverage remains relatively limited).
Figure 81 - % of FTTB connections on total subscriptions (OECD)
Percentage of fibre connections in total broadband subscriptions, June 2015
Japan
Korea Sweden Estonia
Norway Slovak Republic
Iceland
Portugal Slovenia Denmark
Turkey Spain
Hungary
Czech Republic Switzerland Netherlands
Luxembourg United States
Mexico
New Zealand Australia Canada
Italy Poland
Chile
France Finland Austria
Germany Ireland
Belgium
Greece OECD
Latvia Colombia
0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80%
Several other EU countries, including Portugal, Spain, France, Romania and other MS, which benefit from an expanding FTTH/B footprint, albeit at different pace of deployment, may
465 Under the pilot phase of the Europe 2020 Project Bond Initiative, the EIB and the Commission closed in July 2014
the first deal on a broadband project bond (in France – Axione is the beneficiary). The leverage factor foreseen for the broadband part of CEF is around 7x, so it is expected to mobilise around EUR 1 billion. This leverage was exceeded by the Axione deal which had a leverage factor of 14x.
466
KDDI launches GBit/s service 2008 http://www.japantoday.com/category/technology/view/kddi-to-launch-1gbpsfiber-optic-service-in-oct
467
SK Telecom showcases 10Gbit/s service http://www.businesskorea.co.kr/english/news/ict/6789-100x-fasterinternet-sk-broadband-offer-10-gbps-internet
468
See: http://www.unescap.org/sites/default/files/4.1%20Korean%20Broadband%20Policies%20and%20Recommendations.p df
469
https://fiber.google.com/cities/kansascity/plans/
470
See for example http://www.latinpost.com/articles/101338/20151210/google-fiber-vs-att-gigapower-likely-to-wingigabit-race-thanks-to-google.htm
become Europe’s leading countries for VHC connectivity in the years to come 471 . However,
large European countries which have so far been experiencing limited or incremental NGA deployment may lag behind European and global leaders on VHC broadband. illustrates the state of transition from copper to fibre, which is much more advanced in other large economies
than in several large EU countries 472 . Although the picture does not take into account the effect
of cable subscriptions, it gives an idea of the different pace of this transition. Furthermore, rural NGA coverage has been increasing slowly in several countries such as Germany, France, Italy, Austria and Finland, raising the risk of a growing urban/rural digital divide as can be seen in .
Figure 82 – Next generation access (FTTP, VDSL and Docsis 3.0 cable) coverage, June 2015
Source: IHS and VVA - Digital Scoreboard – Connectivity section 473
Challenges to the regulatory framework 474
The evaluation has confirmed that the access-related provisions of the EU Framework have delivered in most Member States competition and market entry at least in standard broadband and other copper-based telecom services, resulting in greater choice and value for consumers, as
also confirmed by the consultation 475 . The market shares of incumbents have fallen steadily on
average across the EU reaching 41% of total subscriptions by July 2015 and average prices for broadband services in the EU have been historically low in comparison with international
benchmarks such as the US or Canada for low data consumptions patterns. 476
Access of all citizens and businesses to high-quality networks at affordable price has become a prerequisite for Europe to reap the full benefits of the emerging digital economy. The existing framework was not primarily designed for, and could have not foreseen, the scale of the need to ensure the widespread availability of modern infrastructure (in rural as well as urban areas), to enable access to emerging applications and services - and to ensure that competition is fostered in an environment of technological change.
471 See SMART 2015/0005 and SMART 2015/0002
472
Fibre subscriptions data includes FTTH, FTTP and FTTB and excludes FTTC. Some countries may have fibre but have not reported figures so they are not included in the chart.
473 Source: : https://ec.europa.eu/digital-single-market/en/download-scoreboard-reports
474
For further discussion regarding the contribution of the regulatory framework to network investment and service take up, please refer to the Evaluation of the regulatory framework for electronic communications SWD, in particular to the sections concerning the effectiveness of access regulation and spectrum regulation.
475
86% of respondents to the Commission’s consultation felt that the EU framework (and the access-related provisions specifically) have contributed either moderately or significantly to achieving the objective of competition. Consultation Q4b, Q19a
476
Source: Mobile Broadband prices (February 2015) https://ec.europa.eu/digital-single-market/en/news/mobilebroadband-prices-february-2015. This study was carried out for the European Commission by Van Dijk.
6.14.3 Towards a connectivity objective
The need for Very High Capacity networks stems by the analysis of the likely connectivity needs over the next ten years based on the current trends and comparing them with performance enhancements required from telecoms networks to meet these needs. While expressing an ambition for the future – especially in the fast changing and transformative digital sector – cannot be fully evidence based, the trends described below, as well as findings of the public consultation on "needs for Internet speed and quality beyond 2020", strongly support the conclusion that Europe needs unconstrained VHC connectivity for all. This growth will be underpinned by technological evolution (a comprehensive overview of the means and technological choices available for network deployment and their implication in terms of performance can be found in Annex 6.3., SMART 2015/0005 and SMART 2015/0002).
The evaluation clearly shows how regulatory choices under the framework can affect the connectivity outcome (section 7.2.3.). Moreover, work conducted for the Commission 477 in support of the evaluation and review of the framework illustrates the impact that national regulatory choices can have on the deployment and upgrade of higher performance networks. The study presents how Spain, France and Portugal's NRAs have focused on stimulating entrants to ‘climb the ladder’ to FTTH through a focus on duct access and in-building wiring in the absence of downstream remedies as well as by promoting co-investment models. These countries have seen developments in FTTH infrastructure competition, but these are largely limited to very dense areas. Market structures in these countries have tended to consolidate towards fewer fixed mobile integrated players. FTTH coverage has grown strongly in Spain and Portugal, but more hesitantly until recently in France. The feasibility of this model has depended on the characteristics of the existing networks, including the availability of ducts.
The main reason for both persistent capacity and coverage constraints, in particular outside urban areas, lies in the huge investments required to roll out very-high-capacity networks. While the 30 Mbps target for 2020 is likely to be largely reached on the basis of current trends, the uncertainty of adoption dynamics remains a key constraint to investment in VHC connectivity.
Despite progress in roll-out of NGA (> 30 Mbps), in the EU significantly fewer households, 49%, have access to networks of at least 100 Mbps, in contrast with Japan and South Korea where according to latest data, 73% and 69% of total broadband connections are fibre. In addition, connectivity in Europe is still overwhelmingly asymmetric, while upload speeds are increasingly important for services, such as cloud computing.
As of July 2015, 70% of European households have basic broadband subscriptions; only 30% of the households are subscribed to NGA above 30Mbps. The trend however, shows that Europeans are rapidly replacing their basic broadband connections with NGA: in 2013 the only 15% of European subscribed to NGA above 30Mbps, while 85% of subscriptions was to a basic broadband connections 478 . Figure 13 showed how dramatically the take-up rate of connection above 100 Mbps is progressing in countries where fibre networks are widely available. Take-up projections of NGA in a 5-10 year timeframe vary, and show significant differences across countries and technologies. For example, taking into account evolving coverage and propensity to take-up NGA, IDATE preliminarily projects that nearly half of households across the EU will take NGA technologies (FTTC, FTTH/B or Docsis 3.0 and successors) by 2020, and nearly two thirds by 2025. However, there are significant differences between countries as shown in the figure below.
Figure 83 - Projections for NGA (>30Mbps) take-up 2015-2025
477 Regulatory, in particular access, regimes for network investment models in Europe (SMART
2015/0002)
478
Source; Digital Scoreboard: https://ec.europa.eu/digital-single-market/en/connectivity
Source: IDATE
As today not all NGA networks can deliver 100 Mbps, the picture above implies that without appropriate investment incentives, Europe is likely to miss the target of having 50% take-up of 100 Mbps services by 2020.
As reported in the evaluation on stakeholders' views (section 7.1.1.) some Member States, the European Telecommunications Network Operators' Association (ETNO) and the large majority of the incumbents go as far as suggesting, via the public consultation conducted in light of the review, that investment should be made an explicit objective, next to competition, given the significant network rollout and upgrade needs in the coming years. This would imply amending the framework; among others access regulation, to favour dynamic efficiency gains over static ones. In areas where infrastructure competition is not viable, competition would be "for the market" rather than "in the market". Many other stakeholders including alternative operators and consumer associations stress, on the other hand that competition would not survive outside the regulatory framework and that the latter should not favour investment at the expense of competition (and thereby also at the expense of the consumer outcomes that go along with competition).
However, the findings of the access study and the forecast summarised in section 1.5 seem to show the legitimacy of the connectivity objective in the medium run.
6.14.4 What is the EU dimension of the problem?
The state of play and the European dimension of the connectivity problem There is a particularly strong rationale for EU action in the context of the challenges of the DSM. Digital services (including calls, messaging and entertainment) are increasingly offered on a pan-European or even global basis. In turn, digital services for consumers and businesses rely on ubiquitous connectivity, in some cases requiring VHC and/or reliability. Connectivity is a vital enabler for
the DSM 479 and warrants an EU-wide response, even if network deployments are mainly local in nature. The figure 480 below gives an idea of the spillovers that are determined by communication
infrastructures on the wider European economy.
Figure 84 – GDP contributions from the Digital economy
479
See EC Digital Single Market Communication May 2015 http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/?uri=celex%3A52015DC0192
480
Source: SMART 2015/0005,.
• Digital
Digital Single Digitalisation of
market industry economy
+€415bln +110bln pa
• Information 4% GDP Communications
Technology (ICT)
1.3% GDP • Communications Infrastructure
The limited connectivity available in Europe already today negatively affects EU citizens', businesses' and public authorities' capacity to produce, share and benefit from innovative digital products and services. Moreover, the competitiveness of the wider economy, not least of multinational companies based in the EU, is affected as high speed, high quality communications services and networks have an economic effect across all business sectors in Europe. As mentioned in section 1.2.1, it is important to take into account that albeit networks are local in nature, (and will probably get even more local in the future with the proliferation of small fibre operators such as in Sweden) the problem of suboptimal investment is a European problem, as even local networks are financed from international and cross-border capital markets. So despite the local nature of the networks, connectivity and investment have a clear internal market dimension and the review should strive to induce policies which are more favourable to investment without jeopardising the existing objectives.
According to the macroeconomic model elaborated for this study (see Section 4.1.1 and Annex 5), if all the preferred options are pursued as a result of the review of the electronic communications framework, we expect expanded market-driven investment and consumption and a cumulative effect on growth of 1.45% and on employment of 0.18% in 2025, assuming that the reforms are implemented by 2020.
In general, digital technologies and ICT have been in the last twenty years an enabler for the emergence and the expansion of new business models such as the sharing economy, crowdsourcing of ideas and solutions for large companies, mutualisation of software (SaaS), including in the cloud. Experience from the harmonisation of approaches to previous generation
technologies and solutions, notably from the GSM Directive, 481 LLU Regulation, 482 and the Leased Line Directive 483 suggests that clear and co-ordinated action at EU level to implement
best practice in relation to connectivity can provide an important stimulus for deployment and take-up, raising the performance of the EU as a whole, compared with action that could be taken by MS individually. This is illustrated by Figure 85, which shows how broadband take-up in Europe expanded in the years following the adoption of the LLU Regulation in 2000, which applied best practice methods for broadband promotion (until then applied only in a few countries such as Germany) more widely across the EU.
481
Council Directive 87/372/EEC i http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:31987L0372:en:HTML
482
Regulation EC 2887/2000 i http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=CELEX%3A32000R2887
483
http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=CELEX%3A31992L0044
Figure 85 - Broadband trends in Europe following the LLU Regulation (2000)
Source: WIK based on Cocom data (except 2002 – OECD) and extrapolations
The 2002 Framework generally enhanced the flexibility of market regulation to deal with different economic circumstances in the MS (via market definition and SMP identification), and the 2009 review enhanced technological and service neutrality in spectrum bands (in contrast to the approach of the GSM directive).
This has allowed for a much more flexible and sophisticated approach to regulation, which can take economically-based decisions on a case-by-case basis. Nevertheless there is still is a clear need for a degree of EU-level steering to define bottlenecks and ultimately to meet common needs . This is recognised in the current framework through a level of flexibility which allows coping with new technological and market circumstances.
Several of the issues raised by the stakeholders and in the implementation experience involve cross-border challenges, such as numbering needs and roaming issues in relation to IoT, spectrum coordination and consumer protection, or businesses' need for seamless connectivity across multiple sites and countries. For example, the lack of European cross border coordination on the timing of allocation and assignment creates cross border interference problems and prevents services developing across the whole EU territory.
The heterogeneity in the implementation at national level of consumer protection as a result of different national legislation brought about by the current minimum harmonisation approach has impacted the effectiveness and efficiency of the rules and reflects the need for a coherent approach at EU level. Consistency in consumer protection standards across borders would avert further fragmentation along national lines and facilitate compliance for multi-territorial operations. Further harmonisation of end-user rights in the EU, coupled with deregulation where warranted, should thus result in a modernised set of consumer protections rules, providing higher confidence among end-users and making it easier for providers of communications services to comply with legislation and reducing unnecessary compliance costs.
6.14.5 Baseline analysis: how would the problem evolve without intervention
This section complements and deepens the analysis of the baseline presented in section 1.5
As mentioned therein, the existing framework has delivered more competition, better prices and choice for consumers, and spurred operators to invest in upgrading their networks at least in some areas. Today virtually all EU citizens have access to basic broadband networks (97% fixed
broadband connections according to the DESI index 2016 484 ) and increasing numbers of citizens
and businesses have access to networks (Next Generation Access – NGA- connectivity)
allowing at least 30 Mbps download speed (70.9% NGA general coverage 485 in EU according to
DESI 2016 – see section 1.4.1 for more data). Only some countries, such as Malta, Lithuania, Belgium and the Netherlands, already enjoy nearly comprehensive coverage of NGA networks, in most of those cases probably mainly thanks to the competitive impulse provided by legacy
cable networks, which could be upgraded at relatively low cost 486 . NGA coverage in countries
which lack extensive cable has been slow to develop in many cases (Italy or Greece being emblematic). Moreover, a large part of the NGA coverage beyond the cable footprint in many countries (UK or Germany, for instance) has been achieved through only partial upgrades of the legacy copper loop (FTTC), rather than full upgrades (FTTH/B). As investigated in study SMART 2015/0002, the former approach may not be sufficient to cope with the data consumptions under the most ambitious scenario forecast.
A key development since the framework was originally conceived is that legacy telephone and cable (coaxial) networks, including the copper ‘local loops’, are in the process of being upgraded with fibre and other solutions which improve broadband performance.
In terms of demand, these enhancements are needed to enable customers to enjoy better quality in online services including online video and cloud applications, as well as enabling multi-screen viewing, which is becoming increasingly prevalent in European households with the proliferation of devices as illustrated in figure 11 above.
Figure 86 - Europe IP Traffic and Service Adoption Drivers
Source: Cisco VNI Global IP Traffic forecast 2014-2019 – Europe includes Western Europe + CEE, excluding Russia
According to CISCO, Global IP traffic will increase threefold over the next 5 years. Overall, IP
traffic will grow at a compound annual growth rate (CAGR) of 21 percent from 2013 to 2018 487 .
The widespread adoption of cloud services, the number of connected devices (IoT), the booming M2M industry, contribute to further increase the traffic load on communications networks. In particular, as businesses and consumers exchange their data with the cloud, this will also lead to a modified demand pattern for upload traffic. Hence, while most of the traffic will still be in
484
The Digital Economy and Society Index (DESI) is a composite index developed by the European Commission (DG CNECT) to assess the development of EU countries towards a digital economy and society. It aggregates a set of relevant indicators structured around 5 dimensions: Connectivity, Human Capital, Use of Internet, Integration of Digital Technology and Digital Public Services. For more information about the DESI please refer to http://ec.europa.eu/digital-agenda/en/digital-agenda-scoreboard
485
NGA broadband coverage/availability (as a % of households) with Next Generation Access including the following technologies: FTTH, FTTB, Cable Docsis 3.0, VDSL and other superfast broadband (at least 30 Mbps download)
486
Several studies highlight the role played by cable in stimulating NGA deployments including SMART 2015/0002, WIK-Consult (2015) for Ofcom ‘Competition and Investment: analysing the drivers of superfast broadband’, and the EP (2013) study ‘Entertainment X.0 to boost broadband deployment’
487
Source: CISCO VNI index, see: http://www.cisco.com/c/en/us/solutions/service-provider/visual-networking-index-vni/index.html
download, demand for upload will increase, as well as the need for lower latency for applications such as cloud computing and e-health, parameters included in the VHC concept.
The trends explained above increase the demand for capacity and certain quality characteristic of connectivity networks. There is an emerging consensus among industry players and investors that in the medium and long run connectivity providers, both fixed and mobile, will have to rely on (nearly) ubiquitous fibre infrastructures coming very close to users' premises, to support their business, especially considering the expected requirements of 5G.
Gigabit connectivity is also foreseen in projections by Deloitte 488 as a requirement to meet the aggregate demand from dozens of connected devices in a home. This is becoming the norm in European households where several users consumer bandwidth from several devices at once. Deloitte further notes that “demand for connectivity has evolved symbiotically: as faster speeds have become available, the range of applications supported has increased and the viable number of devices per person has steadily risen.”
In terms of supply of NGA in commercially viable areas, forecasts from IDATE based on market intelligence (see figure below) suggest that upgrades to NGA and VHC networks will continue, but at a relatively gradual pace.
Figure 87 - Projected take-up of NGA by technology (to 2025)
Source: IDATE, SMART 2015/0002
IDATE projections suggest that by 2020 (see figure above), even under very optimistic assumptions (assuming FTTC/vDSL delivers 100Mbit/s in practice), around 16 countries may miss the DAE targets of 50% households taking up at least a 100 Mbps connection, and that within the 16 affected countries the target will be missed by around 25m households. Under a more conservative assumption, whereby only FTTH/B and cable are considered as reliably offering more than 100Mbit/s, the gap in meeting the target would amount to around 27m households. In reality other advanced hybrid copper-based solutions may deliver the required speed provided the local loop is sufficiently short. Countries with limited historic cable competition such as Italy and Greece are included amongst those considered likely to miss the targets, while countries which have been characterised by strong FTTC, coverage could fail to
meet targets under the stricter assessment 489 .
488 Deloitte Technology, Media and Telecommunications Predictions 2016
489
For additional deployment forecasts see , SMART 2015/0002.
This pace of development may be sufficient to meet the needs of some users, but is likely to limit the potential for more demanding users including small business and home office users and may not be sufficient to enable Europe to fully benefit from a connected economy and society. As explained in more detail in the support study SMART 2015/0005, chapter 1, the demand for data is booming and the scenarios considered are mostly rather conservative.
Concerning rural NGA deployment, existing regulatory practice and outcomes vary across the EU as shown in case studies for SMART 2015/0002. If the current varying practices remain, the current status of uneven rural deployment is likely to persist, resulting in patchy access in rural communities to broadband capable of reaping the benefits from the social and economic integration that digitisation may bring. This process is likely to have repercussions on public finances, especially if accompanied by ageing population. Challenge areas could in theory be addressed through public subsidies, but these are by no means sufficient. The costs of achieving DAE targets also in rural areas are exposed above in section 6.14.1.
An estimate of the connectivity problem in the future (2025 and beyond) can be inferred from asking (1) whether there is likely to be a gap between bandwidth demand and NGA deployed; (2) whether future demands can be met through incremental upgrades of existing copper and coax (cable) networks or only through FTTH/B; and (3) the extent to which future mobile technologies (5G) will be able to rely on fixed networks for backhaul and other data transmission needs. The size of Europe’s bandwidth challenge can be seen most vividly by comparing where we are today with what would be needed to benefit from all aspects of a connected society in 2025 as assessed in more detail in SMART 2015/0002 and SMART 2015/005 490 .
According to Samknows, average download speeds achieved in Europe in 2014 were
24Mbit/s.491 If investment in NGA technologies continues at its current levels, IDATE has
projected that average download speeds would reach around 200Mbit/s- by 2025,492 while upload speeds would reach around 90Mbit/s. Based on trends in video and cloud usage under the ‘status quo’, IDATE has also estimated that bandwidth use in the EU may expand from 62GB
per line per month in 2025 to 298GB per line.493 This may seem significant, and for households
used to experiencing restricted bandwidths,494 it may be appear enough.
As mentioned in section Error! Reference source not found.1.5 there is evidence suggesting
that in the telecom sector demand responds to supply, 495 and that restricted download and
upload speeds may limit the types of usage and applications that might otherwise emerge. In Sweden, following an early boost by the central government, one out of every two municipalities is involved in fibre to the business and fibre to the home deployments. This has led to very high
take-up: as of July 2015, 68% of the broadband connections in Sweden are NGA 496 , achieved
490
In the context of the Expert Panel conducted under SMART 2015/005 – See Annex 13 for more detail, Prof. Brett Frischmann observed that current demand expressed by end-users may fail to reflect the innovation potential in the market, which could be unlocked through more performant infrastructure.
491
Page 115 Samknows for EC Oct 2014 Quality of Broadband Services in the EU
492
In the context of SMART 2015/0002 IDATE forecast likely uptake of NGA by technology to 2025 and based speeds and speed growth per technology on the basis of Samknows data. According to Akamai speed measurements, average speeds have been increasing by 16% per annum across a range of geographies. An alternative approach of extending this projection would result in speeds of around 150Mbit/s in 2025.
493
SMART 2015/0002 494 Many Internet users are already experiencing challenges with the bandwidth they have available. Almost four in ten respondents to the Eurobarometer survey of 2014 noted that they had experienced difficulties accessing online content or applications as a result of insufficient speed of download capacities.
495
Data from the UK regulator Ofcom for example suggests that download bandwidth consumption for NGA (FTTC and FTTP) networks was around two times higher than bandwidth consumption for non-NGA networks, with significantly higher use of upload capacity. This evidence of higher usage being associated with the availability of NGA is supported by the case study of Palaiseau in France, which has been the subject of a pilot trial for the switchoff of Orange copper customers and migration to FTTH networks. In this case it was observed that the average Internet traffic of Orange’s broadband customers as well as their consumption of video-on-demand was multiplied by a factor of three. Importantly, this trial also resulted in fibre clients’ usage of upload bandwidth being increased 8 times, due to changes in Internet usage and an increased usage of cloud-based services.
496
See annex 6.
predominantly through FTTH and FTTB connections. Where FTTH is widespread, the availability of fibre makes extending fibre to base stations far more feasible and efficient. This is well illustrated by the example of 4G in Stockholm where the world’s first 4G deployment took
place helped by the virtually 100% fibre coverage. 497 If bandwidth needs are calculated on the
basis of what might be required to run certain applications, a case study of the German market providing a forecast for 2025 suggests that an average user might require 150-500Mbit/s downstream with more than 100Mbit/s up, while high-end users including those running small or home offices might require 1Gbit/s in download and more than 600 Mbps in upload (see SMART 2015/0005). This bandwidth would be used not only for multi-screen ultra HD video, but also for applications such as cloud and e-health as well as for home working and small business needs.
Figure 88 - Model of market potential – Germany 2025
As shown in figure 14 data rates required by the most demanding users could reach 1 Gbit/s or more on the downstream link by 2025, while a significant proportion of households and offices could demand download speeds of 500-1000Mbit/s and 300-600Mbit/s upstream by 2025. This scenario therefore sets the upper bounds for potential users (including business user) demands in the medium term – though it is worth noting that even a less ambitious scenario will need the fibre rollout to reach far deeper into most of the present networks.
On the subject of inconsistency in the implementation of the framework, there is evidence that without further direction at EU level, this problem is likely to persist and may worsen, in part because when new technologies and services emerge they lack the harmonisation that was historically required through EU legislation, and may not achieve adequate levels of harmonisation through voluntary standardisation alone. Concerns over the impact of fragmentation on business users, in particular multi-national ones, provide an example of the enduring nature of these problems and difficulties in using current tools to address them. Concerns over fragmentation in the market for business communications were first raised in a survey conducted by the predecessor to BEREC, the European Regulators Group (ERG) in 2009, 498 validated in a further survey published in 2013, 499 and have subsequently been reaffirmed by business end-users in the context of studies for the EC in 2015 500 and 2016. 501 Yet
497
Source: Vodafone’s call for the Gigabit Society, Dec. 2015
498
ERG report on the regulation of access products necessary to deliver business connectivity services ERG (09) 51 http://berec.europa.eu/doc/publications/2009/erg_09_51_business_services_paper_final.pdf
499
WIK (2013) Business Communications, economic growth and the competitive challenge
500
SMART 2014/0023 Access and Interoperability standards for the promotion of the internal market for electronic communications
501
SMART 2015/0002 access and investment
in an interview conducted in 2016 for SMART 2015/0002, INTUG observed that it still had concerns over the ability of business issues to be effectively addressed under the existing institutional set-up.
Concerning future generations of wholesale access products for residential customers and small business, the experience of a new product designed as a partial replacement for LLU on NGA networks, such as ‘VULA’ (Virtual Unbundled Local Access) or a WDM (Wavelength Division Multiplexing) based access product provides a warning that without efforts to apply a European ‘standard’ (as was created with ‘local loop unbundling’ on copper networks) any future technological upgrades in fixed access networks are likely to result in duplicate efforts to develop new wholesale access solutions and divergent implementations at national level. As seen with the past implementation of VULA, this may result in slow take-up of wholesale offers of future generations of fixed access infrastructure and therefore – especially in the early phase - reduced levels of choice for consumers in areas where competition cannot be delivered through infrastructure-based competition alone. In turn, this may dampen take-up of new technologies in the early deployment phase. 502
Lastly, in view of the fact that the preparation by NRAs of market analysis often coincides with three year period between market reviews and results in delays of several years, the perpetuation of the existing three year market review cycle, is likely to result in insufficient time for the previous reviews to be confirmed and effectively implemented 503 and their effects to be known. Additionally, the continued re-evaluation and re-calibration of regulation conflicts with the aim
of many regulators to provide longer-term certainty and potentially long-term remedies 504 in
order to provide more durable solutions that offer greater certainty to operators and investors.
Overall we can state that a no change scenario would lead to a persisting digital divide for citizens and SMEs, sub-optimal economic development outcomes, sub-optimal allocation of capital, lack of consumer trust in digital services, lower take up of innovation and loss of competitiveness of EU industry. A review of studies on standard speed broadband suggests that an increase of 10% in standard broadband penetration could contribute between 0.25% to 1.38%
to GDP growth. 505 There is also a small, but expanding body of literature highlighting how the
effects of faster broadband through fibre connectivity could boost growth further and offer a new
lease of life to rural communities 506 .
Promotion of the interests of end-users, including the provision of a safety-net through the universal service obligations, is another principal objective of the regulatory framework, as it ensures that consumers can participate in the digital society and fully reap the benefits of a competitive market. Overall the framework has been successful in safeguarding consumer protection, even when this is not fully translated in increased consumer satisfaction. Given the increasing role of connectivity and electronic communications services in today's European economy, it is important to continue protecting end users' interest.
502
Evidence from standard broadband suggests that unbundling played a role in accelerating take-up in the early deployment (but not later phase). It also had a positive impact on service quality. See unbundling the incumbent – evidence from UK broadband Nardotto, Valletti, Verboven (2015) http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2505035 . SMART 2014/0024 also shows how NGA take-up could have been accelerated if customers of entrants had been converted to NGA at the same rate as those of incumbents
503
This is especially true in the case of appealed decisions
504
Long-term discounts exceeding 3 years have been negotiated for wholesale FTTC/VDSL bitstream access in NL and Germany. In France, one amongst a number of justifications provided by ARCEP in interview for SMART 2015/0002 for pursuing symmetric rather than asymmetric regulation to address fibre bottlenecks was the need to provide a framework for longer term solutions (in this case on the basis of IRU)..
505
Among others: Crandall, R., Lehr, W., and Litan, R. (2007), The Effects of Broadband Deployment on Output and Employment: A Cross-sectional Analysis of U.S. Data, Issues in Economic Policy, 6; Czernich, N., Falck, O., Kretschmer T., and Woessman, L. (2011), Broadband infrastructure and economic growth, Economic Journal, 121(552); Koutroumpis, P. (2009). The Economic Impact of Broadband on Growth: A Simultaneous Approach, Telecommunications Policy, 33; Qiang, C. Z., and Rossotto, C. M. (2009), Economic Impacts of Broadband, In Information and Communications for Development 2009: Extending Reach and Increasing Impact, 35– 50.Washington, DC: World Bank.
506
See for further studies SMART 005/2015
Current rules on contracts content, duration and termination, transparency on tariffs, quality of service and other conditions, potential minimum quality of service requirements, switching and number portability have enabled consumers to take advantage of a competitive market.
Regarding switching, the number of porting transactions has increased, in particular in relation to mobile numbers, with switching rates above other subscription-based industries, even if certain practical implementation difficulties still affect consumers (e.g. loss of service during switching).
National rules have ensured transparency of information on services and prices by providers, including in some cases the provision of online tools comparing prices and services; rules on contract duration have been transposed so that the initial commitment period does not exceed 24 months, while also ensuring that providers offer users the possibility to subscribe to a contract with a maximum duration of 12 months; some Member States have adopted detailed rules regarding consumer protection safeguards in case of unilateral changes to contract conditions.
Despite the above, consumers still refer to issues related to transparency and quality of service, in particular with regards to the internet access service. This problem is especially acute when access to the internet service is bundled with other communications service, resulting in 24% of consumers not finding easy to compare prices of bundles, while evidence shows that an increasing number of consumers on most Member States opt for this service delivery mode.
The provisions on security and integrity of networks and services have contributed to strengthening the European telecom infrastructure’s resilience and services availability across the EU. Yet effectiveness of the provisions is not complete and this would be related to the fact that security obligations cover only electronic communications providers.
As explained in the problem definition, only providers of traditional communication services have to comply with sector specific rules safeguarding end-user's interests. Providers of communications service over the internet (OTTs) are not subject to these sector-specific rights and obligations, even when their services are used by the end-users to cover the same or similar communications needs as the traditional electronic communications services.
Significant changes or further evolution of the problem are not foreseeable with regards to services and end-user protection, absent further intervention at EU level. Uncertainty about the scope of sector specific rights and obligations and gaps in consumer protection would persist, which would in turn lead to a further fragmentation of the internal market and impede adoption of new services.
Rules on universal service aim at providing a safety net ensuring that the most vulnerable in society as well as those in more remote areas can receive basic services. They cover both connectivity and service aspects, as well as the affordability of tariffs and accessibility for disabled users. The provisions permit financing of any ‘net cost’ of universal service obligations either through a levy on operators or through public funds, where such a net cost would otherwise constitute an unfair burden to the designated Universal Service Obligation (USO) operator.
In the absence of intervention at EU level, Member States would likely take increasingly different approaches in universal service obligations by removing outdated services from the scope. Consistency and coherence of the universal service regime across Member States would reduce without a common approach towards the inclusion of broadband in the universal service scope. The sectorial financing mechanism would continue being a possibility for financing. The costs of financing the universal service obligation in the Member States would likely remain the same, depending on possible national approaches. Looking towards future challenges which could not be addressed in the absence of more consistent and effective intervention, the most immediate and significant new technological development is the introduction of 5G (planned for the early 2020s). Indeed, as an ongoing Commission study507 confirms, 5G is expected to deliver 1 gigabit per second simultaneously to, for instance, many workers on the same floor. In addition, it offers enhanced spectral efficiency, enhanced signalling efficiency and reduced latency compared to 4G. 5G is also expected to be a key enabler for M2M communications and the IoT.
The economic benefits of successful, fast and coordinated deployment of 5G across the EU are very significant and they have been estimated at 146bn EUR per year and the creation of 2.39m
jobs 508. These estimates only consider the most immediate impacts of a delay including the
sectors that are most directly affected. It is likely that the full impacts of 5G would only materialise at a later stage and that they would affect many more sectors of the economy. Later deployment of 5G services would therefore also lead to delays in these ripple effects throughout the wider economy.
A failure to achieve a single market in electronic communications can in itself impose considerable costs. This is especially true for multi-national businesses, which require not only the availability of connections in disperse locations, but also uniform conditions for provisioning, repair and quality guarantees. In a 2013 study “Business communications, economic growth and the competitive challenge”, WIK estimated that the creation of a single market enabling the seamless provision of business communications services could lead to efficiency gains and boost productivity providing economic benefits of up to €90bln per annum over time. 509
Meanwhile, a 2011 study conducted for the EC – steps towards a truly Internal Market for ecommunications
510 – identified substantial benefits from greater ‘standardisation’ of solutions
within the EU, including: (i) Advantages for multinational corporations – making Europe a more attractive location for headquarters, branch offices and production facilities; (ii) economies of scale for manufacturers of telecoms systems, which could benefit from a lesser need for customisation (iii) improvements in e-Health, e-Learning and business to business services. The authors concluded that increased standardisation could provide annual gains of 0.3%-0.45% GDP (€35bln-€55bln) and cautioned that failing to reach standardised solutions would affect future pan-European roll-out as well as the development of premium over-the-top-services. The study also examined the impact of harmonised ‘best practice’ in the promotion of competition in telecoms, and concluded that a fully-harmonised European approach could provide gains of 0.22% and 0.44% of GDP (€27bln - 55bln) by delivering lower prices, higher quality and greater investments.
507
SMART 2015/0003, Substantive issues for review: market entry, management of scarce resources, and general end-user issues
508
SMART 2014/0008, Identification and quantification of key socio-economic data to support strategic planning for the introduction of 5G in Europe
509
The gains are associated with a welfare gain from lower prices, efficiency gains from an improvement in ICT processes and productivity gains through a reorganisation of business processes
510
Ecorys/TNO/TU Delft (2011) ‘Steps towards a truly internal market for electronic communications’ https://ec.europa.eu/digital-agenda/en/news/steps-towards-truly-internal-market
6.15 ANNEX 15 - Glossary and Bibliography
ADR: Alternative Dispute Resolution
ADSL: Asymmetric Digital Subscriber Line
ARPU: Average Revenue Per User
ARCEP: Autorité de régulation des communications électroniques et des postes
ASQ – Assured Service Quality
BCG: Boston Consulting Group
BEREC: Body of European Regulators
BEUC: Bureau Européen des Unions de Consommateurs (The European Consumer Organisation)
CAGR: Compound Annual Growth Rate
CAP: Content and Applications Provider
CAPEX: Capital expenditure
CEPT: European Conference of Post and Telecom Administrations
COCOM: Communications Committee
CRM: Customer Relationship Management
DAE: Digital Agenda for Europe
DESI: Digital Economy and Society Index
DG CNECT: European Commission Directorate General for Communications Networks, Content and Technology
DNS: Domain Name System
DSM: Digital Single Market
ECHR: European Charter of Human Rights
EC: European Commission
ECN: Electronic Communication Networks
ECNS: Electronic Communication Networks and Services
ECS: Electronic Communication Services
ECTA: European Competitive Telecommunications Association
EFIS: ECO (European Communication Office) Frequency Information System eMBB: enhanced mobile broadband
EP: European Parliament
EPG: Electronic Programme Guide
ERA: European Railway Agency
ERP: Enterprise Resource Planning
ERT: European Round Table for Industrialists
ESIF: European Structural and Investment Funds
ETNO: European Telecommunications Network Operators' Association
ETNS: European Telephone Numbering Space
ETSI: European Telecommunications Standards Institute
EU: European Union
EUR: euro (currency)
FCC: U.S. Federal Communications Commission
FTE: Full Time Equivalent
FTTB: Fibre to the Building
FTTC: Fibre to the Cabinet
FTTH: Fibre to the Home
FTTP: Fibre to the Premises
FTTx: Fibre to the x
FWA: Fixed Wireless Access
FWD: Framework directive
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
GHz: Gigahertz
GPS: Global Positioning System
GPT: General Purpose Technology
GSM: Global System for Mobile Communications
GSMA: GSM Association
HFC: Hybrid Fibre Coaxial technology
HSPA: High Speed Packet Access
IA: Impact Assessment
IAS: Internet Access Services
IASG: Impact Assessment Steering Group
ICT: Information and Communications Technology
INTUG: International Telecommunications Users Group
IoT: Internet of Things
IP: Internet Protocol
IPR: Intellectual Property Rights
IPTV: Internet Protocol Television
ISP: Internet Service Provider
IT: Information Technology
ITRE: European Parliament Committee on Industry, Research and Energy
LLU: Local Loop Unbundling
LTE: Long Term Evolution
M2M: Machine-to-Machine
MEP: Member of the European Parliament
MHz: Megahertz
MNC: Mobile network code
MNO: Mobile Network Operators
MS: Member States
MSC/MNC: multi-site/multi-national corporations
MVNO: Mobile Virtual Network Operators
NFV: Network Function Virtualisation
NGA: Next Generation Access
NIS: Network and Information Security
NRA: National Regulation Authority
ODR: Online Dispute Resolution
OECD: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
OTA: over-the-air-provisioning
OTTs: Over The Top players
P2P: Peer-to-Peer
PATS: Public Access Telephony Services
PSAP: Public Safety Answering Point
PSB: Public Service Broadcaster
PSTN: Public Switched Telephone Network
QoS: Quality of Service
R&D: Research & Development
RSC: Radio Spectrum Committee
RSPP: Radio Spectrum Policy Programme
RSPG: Radio Spectrum Policy Group
SDN: Software Defined Networks
SIM: Subscriber Identity Module
SMA: Spectrum Management Authority
SME: Small and Medium Enterprises
SMP: Significant Market Power
SMS: Short Message Service
TFEU: Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union
TTE Council: The Transport, Telecommunications and Energy Council
US: United States of America
USD: Universal Service Directive
USO: Universal Service Obligation
VAT: Value Added Tax
VHC: Very High Capacity
VDSL: Very-high-bit-rate digital subscriber line
VoD: Video on Demand
VoIP: Voice over Internet Protocol
VP: Vice-President
VULA: Virtual Unbundled Local Access
WDM: Wavelength Division Multiplexing
WLR: Wholesale Line Rental
4G: Fourth generation of mobile phone mobile communication technology standards
5G: Fifth generation of mobile phone mobile communication technology standards
15 Sep '16 |
Proposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL establishing the European Electronic Communications Code (Recast) PROPOSAL |
Secretary-General of the European Commission 12252/16 |
The EU Monitor enables its users to keep track of the European process of lawmaking, focusing on the relevant dossiers. It automatically signals developments in your chosen topics of interest. Apologies to unregistered users, we can no longer add new users.This service will discontinue in the near future.