COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT The development of secondary markets for non-performing loans by removing undue impediments to loan servicing by third parties and the transfer of loans (Part 1/2) And Accelerated Extrajudicial Collateral Enforcement (Part 2/2) Accompanying the document Proposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL on credit servicers, credit purchasers and the recovery of collateral - Main contents
Document date | 21-03-2018 |
---|---|
Publication date | 23-03-2018 |
Reference | 7403/18 ADD 1 |
From | Secretary-General of the European Commission, signed by Mr Jordi AYET PUIGARNAU, Director |
External link | original article |
Original document in PDF |
Council of the European Union
Brussels, 21 March 2018 (OR. en)
7403/18
Interinstitutional File: ADD 1
2018/0063 (COD) i
JAI 245 JUSTCIV 69 EF 85 EJUSTICE 18 ECOFIN 270 DRS 15 COMPET 176 EMPL 120 SOC 160 CODEC 427 IA 74
COVER NOTE
From: Secretary-General of the European Commission, signed by Mr Jordi AYET PUIGARNAU, Director
date of receipt: 14 March 2018
To: Mr Jeppe TRANHOLM-MIKKELSEN, Secretary-General of the Council of the European Union
No. Cion doc.: SWD(2018) 75 final PART 1/2
Subject: COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT The development of secondary markets for non-performing loans by
removing undue impediments to loan servicing by third parties and the transfer of loans (Part 1/2) And Accelerated Extrajudicial Collateral Enforcement (Part 2/2) Accompanying the document Proposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL on credit servicers, credit purchasers and the recovery of collateral
Delegations will find attached document SWD(2018) 75 final PART 1/2.
Encl.: SWD(2018) 75 final PART 1/2
EUROPEAN COMMISSION
Brussels, 14.3.2018 SWD(2018) 75 final
PART 1/2
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT
IMPACT ASSESSMENT
The development of secondary markets for non-performing loans by removing undue impediments to loan servicing by third parties and the transfer of loans (Part 1/2)
And
Accelerated Extrajudicial Collateral Enforcement (Part 2/2)
Accompanying the document
Proposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE
COUNCIL
on credit servicers, credit purchasers and the recovery of collateral
{COM(2018) 135 final i} - {SWD(2018) 76 final}
Table of contents
-
1.INTRODUCTION: POLITICAL AND LEGAL CONTEXT ............................................................... 4
-
2.PROBLEM DEFINITION .................................................................................................................. 12
-
3.WHY SHOULD THE EU ACT? ........................................................................................................ 26
-
4.OBJECTIVES: WHAT IS TO BE ACHIEVED? ............................................................................... 29
-
5.WHAT ARE THE AVAILABLE POLICY OPTIONS? .................................................................... 30
-
6.WHAT ARE THE IMPACTS OF THE POLICY OPTIONS? ........................................................... 43
-
7.HOW DO THE OPTIONS COMPARE? ............................................................................................ 54
-
8.PREFERRED OPTIONS .................................................................................................................... 58
-
9.HOW WILL ACTUAL IMPACTS BE MONITORED AND EVALUATED? .................................. 60
LIST OF REFERENCES .............................................................................................................................. 61
ANNEX 1: PROCEDURAL INFORMATION ............................................................................................ 65
-
1.LEAD DG, DECIDE PLANNING/CWP REFERENCES .................................................................. 65
-
2.ORGANISATION AND TIMING ...................................................................................................... 65
-
3.CONSULTATION OF THE RSB....................................................................................................... 65
-
4.EVIDENCE, SOURCES AND QUALITY ......................................................................................... 66
ANNEX 2: STAKEHOLDER CONSULTATION ....................................................................................... 68
CONTEXT.................................................................................................................................................... 68
-
1.COVERAGE AND REPRESENTATIVENESS OF THE CONSULTATION REPLIES ....................... 68
-
2.THE ROLE OF NPLS AND NPL MARKETS ........................................................................................ 70
-
3.MEASURES TARGETING NPL INVESTORS ...................................................................................... 71
-
4.THE ECONOMIC FUNCTION OF LOAN SERVICERS ....................................................................... 73
-
5.POLICY MEASURES TARGETING LOAN SERVICERS ................................................................... 74
ANNEX 3: WHO IS AFFECTED AND HOW? .......................................................................................... 76
-
1.PRACTICAL IMPLICATIONS OF THE INITIATIVE..................................................................... 76
-
2.SUMMARY OF COSTS AND BENEFITS ....................................................................................... 78
ANNEX 4: ANALYTICAL METHODS ..................................................................................................... 87
-
1.A STYLISED VIEW ON DEMAND AND SUPPLY OF THE NPL MARKET ..................................... 87
-
2.CROSS COUNTRY ANALYSIS ............................................................................................................. 92
-
3.QUANTIFYING THE IMPACT OF THE DIFFERENT POLICY OPTIONS ON NPL SECONDARY MARKETS- EXPLANATION AND ASSUMPTIONS ............................................ 99
-
4.TRANSLATING THE SCORES FOR THE ASSESSMENT CRITERIA INTO AN OVERALL RANKING OF THE POLICY OPTIONS ........................................................................................ 110
ANNEX 5: MARKET OVERVIEW .......................................................................................................... 112
-
1.NATURE AND SIZE OF THE NPL MARKET .................................................................................... 112
-
2.NATURE AND SIZE OF THE LOAN SERVICING MARKET .......................................................... 121
ANNEX 6: THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK OF NPL TRANSFERS AND LOAN SERVICERS ..................................................................................................................................... 133
-
1.A STOCKTAKE OF RULES IN THE EU MEMBER STATES: RESULTS OF THE QUESTIONNAIRE TO MEMBER STATES .................................................................................. 133
1.1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ............................................................................................................... 133
1.2 BACKGROUND .................................................................................................................................. 134
1.3. ASSESSMENT OF ANSWERS TO THE QUESTIONNAIRE .......................................................... 135
1.3.1 LOAN SERVICING ACTIVITIES .................................................................................................. 135
-
2.OBSTACLES FLAGGED IN THE PUBLIC CONSULTATION ......................................................... 142
Glossary
Term or acronym Meaning or definition
AECE Accelerated Extrajudicial Collateral Enforcement
AMC Asset management company
CEEC Central and Eastern European Countries
CMU Capital Markets Union
distressed debt Debt securities, bank debt, trade claims or other financial securities (CDS, options, etc.) of companies under financial stress
EBA European Banking Authority
EBITDA Earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortisation
ECB European Central Bank
ECOFIN Economic and Financial Affairs Council
ESRB European Systemic Risk Board
EUR Euro
FED Federal Reserve Board (US central bank)
GDPR General Data Protection Regulation
HQ headquarter
IMF International Monetary Fund
loan loss provisioning amount expense set aside as an allowance for a loan becoming nonperforming
loan servicer firm specialised in the administration of a loan to ensure the collection of debt
MS Member State, Member States
NBER National Bureau of Economic Research
NPL Non-performing loan. Bank loans past due 90 days without the borrower paying the agreed instalments or interest
SMEs Small and medium-sized enterprises
SPV Special Purpose Vehicle: structure used to securitise assets
SSM Single Supervisory Mechanism
-
1.I NTRODUCTION : P OLITICAL AND LEGAL CONTEXT
1.1. The need to address Non-performing Loans in the EU
Following the financial crisis, the regulatory framework for banks has changed substantially. The European Union has taken the lead in implementing reforms agreed globally at the level of the G20 and in the Basel Committee with the objective of reducing risk in the banking sector, reinforcing financial stability and avoiding that taxpayers have to contribute financially to the costs of failing banks. In addition to these measures, the institutional arrangements for the supervision and resolution of banks in the EU have been strengthened fundamentally with the establishment of the first two pillars of the Banking Union (BU): the
Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM) and the Single Resolution Mechanism (SRM). 1 As a
result of these measures, the EU banking sector is in a much better shape today than in previous years.
Nevertheless, several challenges remain to be addressed, including how to decisively address the high stocks of non-performing loans (NPLs) and other non-performing exposures (NPEs) 2 . NPLs have piled up in parts of the EU banking sector in the aftermath of the financial and sovereign crises and ensuing recessions. High levels of NPLs in parts of the banking sector pose significant risks to financial stability and the overall economy in the EU, unlike in other major economies such as the United States or Japan which have previously taken a number of actions to reduce the level of NPLs and repair banks’ balance sheets. 3
High NPL ratios 4 can weigh on a bank's short- and longer-term performance through two
main channels. First, NPLs generate less income than performing loans – thus reducing bank profitability – and may cause losses that diminish the bank's capital. In the most severe cases, these effects can put in question the viability of a bank with potential implications for financial stability. Second, NPLs tie up significant amounts of a bank's resources, both human and financial. 5 Banks saddled with high levels of NPEs have therefore only a limited capacity to provide new credit to viable businesses. Small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) are particularly affected by the reduced credit supply, as they rely on bank lending to a much greater extent than larger companies, thereby affecting economic growth and job creation. 6
1 The third pillar of the Banking Union, the European Deposit Insurance Scheme (EDIS), was proposed by the Commission in November 2015.
2 NPEs include non-performing loans (NPLs), non-performing debt securities and nonperforming offbalance-sheet items. NPLs, which term is well established and commonly used in the policy discussion, represent the largest share of NPEs. Throughout this document the term NPL is meant in a broad sense equivalent to NPE, and hence the two terms are used interchangeably.
3 See, for example, FSC (2017) "Report of the FSC Subgroup on Non-Performing Loans"; FSI (2017) "Resolution of non-performing loans – policy options"; and IMF (2015) "Global Financial Stability Report, Chapter 1: Enhancing policy traction and reducing risks".
4 The term NPL ratio refers to the ratio of non-performing loans to total outstanding loans.
5 A large portion of the employees' time is spent dealing with lengthy procedures required to manage NPLs. As NPLs are considered riskier than performing loans, they may require higher amounts of regulatory capital if left un-provisioned.
6 Simulations by the IMF (2015b) suggest that a reduction of European Non Performing Loans to the historical average ratio (by selling them at net book value i.e. after provisioning) could increase bank capital by EUR 54 billion. This would under some assumptions enable EUR 553 billion in new lending.
For all these reasons, the Commission has for a long time highlighted the urgency of taking the necessary measures to address the risks related to NPLs.
While tackling NPLs is primarily the responsibility of national authorities 7 , there is also a
clear EU dimension of the NPLs issue. Given the high level of economic and financial integration in the EU, and especially within the euro area (EA), there are important potential spill-over effects from Member States with high levels of NPLs to the economies of other
Member States and the EU at large, both in terms of economic growth and financial stability. 8
Weak growth in some Member States due to elevated NPL levels might affect economic growth elsewhere. Also, weak balance sheets of just a few banks can negatively affect investors' general perception of the value and soundness of other EU banks. This can unnecessarily raise the funding costs for the sector as a whole, which may adversely affect the cost of credit to borrowers.
Addressing high stocks of NPLs and their possible future accumulation is therefore essential for restoring the competitiveness of the banking sector, preserving financial stability and supporting lending to create jobs and growth. This analysis is shared by a number of reports from European institutions, international organisations, and think tanks. 9
1.2 Recent evolution of NPLs
The general improvement in NPL ratios over recent years continued in 2017, as did the quality of banks’ loans portfolios. The latest figures confirm the downward trend of the NPL ratio, which declined to 4.6% (Q2 2017), down by roughly 1 percentage point (pp) year-onyear (see Figure 1). This reduction was mainly the result of one ‐off events that impacted all bank ‐size classes, in particular smaller banks. However, the ratio remains elevated when compared to historical norms and to other regions 10 and the total volume of NPLs across the EU is still at the level of EUR 950 billion. 11
The situation differs significantly across Member States (see Figure 2). Several countries still have high NPL ratios (9 had ratios above 10% in the second quarter of 2017), while others have rather low ratios (10 Member States were below 3%).
There is evidence of some progress in reducing NPL ratios in the most affected countries, owing to a combination of policy actions and a stronger macroeconomic environment. However, significant risks to economic growth and financial stability remain and progress is still slow, especially where it is needed the most. Structural impediments continue to hamper a faster fall in NPL stocks. Provisioning is often still too slow and insufficient to allow for effectively resolving and preventing any critical accumulation of NPLs in the future. Among other elements, activity on secondary markets for NPLs is also not yet sufficient to
7 As also underlined in the European Semester recommendations to relevant Member States.
8 See ESRB (2017) and IMF (2015).
9 See ECB (2016, 2017), EBA (2017), FSC (2017), ESRB (2017), IMF (2015a, b), Vienna Initiative (2012), Baudino and Yun (2017), Bruegel (2017), Barba Navaretti et al. (2017).
10 The NPL ratio for both the United States and Japan was around 1.5 % in December 2016.
11 Source: ECB.
substantially contribute to NPL reduction efforts, notwithstanding the increased interest from certain investor groups and the increasing volume of NPL-related transactions.
Figure 1 EU Non-Performing Loans ratio Figure 2: NPL ratio in EU Member States
Gross non-performing loans and advances %
(in % of total gross loans and advances, end-of-period values) 50 Dec-14
Jun-17 6.5
40
5.5
30
4.5
20
3.5 2014-Q4 2015-Q2 2015-Q4 2016-Q2 2016-Q4 2017-Q2 10
Source: European Central Bank European Union
0
AT BE BG CY CZ DE DK EE ES FI FR UK EL HR HU IE IT LT LU LV MT NL PL PT RO SE SI SK Source: ECB. Note: Dec-2014 not available for CZ.
1.3 Towards a comprehensive package of measures to address NPLs
A comprehensive and credible strategy to address NPLs is an essential and urgent step towards restoring the viability of – and hence investor confidence in – the EU banking sector. Pursuing a comprehensive strategy and taking determined action to address NPLs is also essential for the smooth functioning of the Banking Union and the Capital Markets Union (CMU) and for a stable and integrated financial system. In this way, the resilience of the Economic and Monetary Union to adverse shocks will be enhanced by facilitating private risk-sharing across borders, while at the same time reducing the need for public risk-sharing.
Integrating national and EU-level efforts is needed to address the NPL problem, both on the existing NPL stocks and on future NPL flows. Reflecting the EU dimension and building on previous work by the Commission and other competent EU authorities, the Council adopted
in July 2017 an Action Plan To Tackle Non-Performing Loans in Europe. 12 It recognises that
work in this area must be based on a comprehensive approach combining a mix of complementary policy actions, since the complexity of the problem simply does not lend itself to a single ‘silver bullet’ solution.
The Council Action Plan combines various measures by national governments, bank supervisors and EU institutions that improve the tools and incentives for banks to pro-actively address NPLs either by internal work-out or through disposal. In practice, this means enhancing legal frameworks relevant for both the prevention and resolution of NPLs, including the functioning of secondary markets. However, other measures such as improving
12 See http://www.consilium.europa.eu/en/press/press-releases/2017/07/11/conclusions-non-performingloans/
the availability and quality of data on NPLs or improving the market infrastructure (eg. set-up of trading or information platforms) are equally important. If the right pre-conditions are present, tools such as Asset Management Companies are also an efficient way to allow resolution of NPLs while removing NPLs from the banking system in the short term.
The Commission has committed to delivering on the parts of the NPL Action Plan within its remit. Accordingly, the Commission announced in its October 2017 Communication on completing Banking Union a comprehensive package for tackling high NPL ratios, to be put
forward by Spring 2018. 13
This "Spring package" consists of the following measures:
A Blueprint for how national Asset Management Companies (AMCs) can be set up in
compliance with existing EU banking and State aid rules by building on best practices learned from past experiences in Member States.
A legislative initiative to further develop secondary markets for NPLs, especially with
the aim of removing undue impediments to loan servicing by third parties and to the transfer of loans to third parties.
A legislative initiative to enhance the protection of secured creditors by allowing them
more efficient methods of value recovery from secured loans through Accelerated Extrajudicial Collateral Enforcement (AECE). This refers to an expedited and efficient out-of-court enforcement mechanism which enables secured creditors (banks) in all Member States to recover value from collateral granted by companies and
entrepreneurs to secure loans. 14
A legislative initiative amending the Capital Requirement Regulation (CRR), with
regard to the introduction of minimum coverage requirements for incurred and expected losses on future NPLs arising from newly originated loans, in order to backstop potential under-provisioning of future NPLs and prevent their build-up on
banks’ balance sheets.
A way forward to foster the transparency on NPLs in Europe by improving the data
availability and comparability as regards NPLs, and potentially supporting the development by market participants of NPL information platforms or credit registers.
15
13 COM(2017) 592 final i, 11.10.2017, available at: http://ec.europa.eu/finance/docs/law/171011- communication-banking-union_en.pdf .
14 This initiative will remain consistent with and complementary to the Commission proposal of November 2016 for a Directive on, inter alia, preventive restructuring frameworks and would not require harmonisation of actual insolvency provisions.
15 In addition, the Commission is also undertaking a benchmarking exercise of loan enforcement regimes to establish a reliable picture of the delays and value-recovery banks experience when faced with borrowers' defaults, and invites close cooperation from Member States and supervisors to develop a sound and significant benchmarking methodology. In this context, the 2016 Commission proposal for a Directive on business insolvency, restructuring and second chance lays down obligations on Member States to collect comparable data on insolvency and restructuring proceedings.
The Council Action plan initiatives under the responsibility of other EU institutions and competent authorities include, among others:
General guidelines on NPL management applicable to all EU banks;
Detailed guidelines on banks' loan origination, monitoring and internal governance,
addressing in particular transparency and borrower affordability assessment;
Macro-prudential approaches to prevent the emergence of system-wide NPL problems,
taking into account potential pro-cyclicality and financial stability implications of NPL
policy measures;
Enhanced disclosure requirements on banks' asset quality and non-performing loans.
1.4 Commonalities and interdependencies of the various measures
The legislative and non-legislative initiatives of the Council Action plan are interlinked and mutually reinforcing. They should create the appropriate environment for dealing with NPLs on banks' balance sheets. Some of them have an impact on the reduction of the current stock of NPLs, and all are relevant for reducing risks of future NPL accumulation. Their impact is expected to be different across Member States and affected institutions. Some will have a stronger impact on banks' ex ante risk assessment at loan origination, some will foster swift recognition and better management of NPLs, and others will enhance the market value of such NPLs.
The Commission's three legislative initiatives, namely i) statutory prudential backstops for loan loss coverage; ii) the development of secondary markets for NPLs, and iii) accelerated extrajudicial collateral enforcement mechanisms, mutually reinforce each other and also interact with the other measures of the Council Action Plan. For example, the prudential backstops initiative ensures that credit losses on future NPLs are sufficiently covered, making their resolution and/or disposal easier. These effects would be complemented by better developed secondary markets for NPLs as these would make demand for NPLs more competitive and raise their market value. Furthermore, accelerated collateral enforcement as a swift mechanism for recovery of collateral value would reduce the costs for resolving NPLs. These interactions are described in greater detail in the below box.
Figure 3 Commission's policy initiatives within the NPL Action Plan
Statutory prudential backstops
Banks' immediate
recognition of NPLs Bank supervision
Powers of bank supervisors
Insolvency reform and loan
Better risk assessment in enforcement lending decisions Reform of debt restructuring and recovery,
insolvency frameworks Collateral enforcement
Asset management Higher recovery value of companies
NPLs
Enabling secondary Data standardization and markets for NPLs transaction platforms
Market access to NPL investors and loan servicers
Box on the reinforcement effects between the Commission's legislative initiatives
This box assesses the possible reinforcement effects between the three initiatives of the Spring package, namely i) statutory prudential backstops for loan loss coverage; ii) development of secondary markets for NPLs, and iii) accelerated extrajudicial collateral enforcement mechanisms. As is the usual practice, each individual impact assessment gauges the incremental effects of the proposed measure against a no policy change baseline. The underlying idea of the NPL package is, however, that the effects of each initiative will be mutually enhancing. The exact quantification of these feedback effects is a quite complex exercise as it is subject to strong modelling uncertainty. This box hence provides a qualitative description of the feedback channels and their relative strength.
Figure 4 - The reinforcement effects between the initiatives of the NPL package
Effects of Accelerated extrajudicial collateral enforcement (AECE) on other initiatives
As AECE becomes more popular and used by credit institutions, the statutory prudential backstop measures would be less binding. Indeed, banks would tend to restructure, recover or dispose of their NPLs earlier and at a higher rate. They would be less affected by the need to increase provisioning as time goes by, as required by the prudential backstops measures.
Given that the AECE feature would follow the NPLs following their disposal to a third party, this would help the development of the secondary market by increasing investor participation and thereby its liquidity (NPL demand-side effects). In particular, shorter time of resolution and increased recovery, as expected with AECE, would increase the bid prices. Moreover, the harmonization achieved by AECE would foster development of pan-European NPL investors, further improving market liquidity.
Effects of Statutory prudential backstops on other initiatives
The more costly in terms of higher provisioning it becomes for banks to keep secured corporate NPLs on their balance sheets due to the new prudential backstop rules, the higher the incentives for banks to restructure, recover or dispose of NPLs quicker and earlier, and hence the higher the use of AECE directly (by triggering it) or indirectly (by disposing of the NPL to a third party).
Holding NPLs on the balance sheet will become costly over time, providing an incentive for banks to dispose of NPLs on the secondary markets at an early stage, when the backstops require less minimum coverage. Once the minimum coverage level required by the backstops becomes more binding, the carrying book value of NPLs will be reduced. Both of these mechanisms would ensure more sellers participation on the secondary market (NPL supply-side effect), thereby reducing the ask price of NPLs.
Effects of the development of secondary markets for NPLs on other initiatives
Improved investor participation and better functioning of secondary markets would reduce the bid-ask spread and increase the volume of NPLs that are transferred to third parties. Banks would dispose of NPLs more eagerly and at an earlier stage, therefore the provisioning backstop would be less often binding.
With a more liquid and better functioning secondary market for NPLs where investors show appetite for NPLs with the AECE feature, there would be additional incentives for credit institutions to use AECE at origination of new loans. This indirect feedback effect would become active once sellers realise that it is easier to dispose of NPLs having the AECE feature to third party investors.
The effectiveness of the three aforementioned legislative measures would increase if banks are adequately capitalised in the future. Better capitalised banks will be more eager to sell NPLs in the secondary market or to realise the collateral of a non-performing loan in a timely fashion. Furthermore, statutory minimum coverage requirements would provide strong incentives for banks' management to prevent the accumulation of future NPLs through better NPL management and stronger loan origination practices. This will reinforce the expected effects of the EBA’s and ECB’s work on banks' loan origination, NPL management, monitoring and internal governance practices. Work on NPL information and market infrastructure would further enhance the functioning of NPLs secondary markets. Lastly, measures related to loan enforcement would complement the Commission's November 2016 proposal for a Directive on business insolvency, preventive restructuring and second chance, by increasing the chances that viable businesses survive while non-viable activities are swiftly resolved. 16
1.5 The scope of the impact assessment
The initiative to develop secondary markets for NPLs discussed in this text focuses on a specific issue that is not taken up in any of the other policy measures in the Action Plan, namely to remove impediments to transfers of NPLs from banks to other entities and to simplify and harmonise requirements for loan servicers. Being one of the four key areas in the Action Plan, stakeholders signalled the importance of secondary markets for the resolution of NPLs in the public consultation that preceded this impact assessment (see Annex 2) as did banks contributing to the EBA Risk Assessment Questionnaire. In the latter, they considered the lack of secondary markets for NPLs one of the two most important impediments to the resolution of NPLs. 17
The initiative analysed here is unique among all measures following the Council Action Plan as it is the only legislative measure that targets an increase in demand and to raise competitive pressure on the demand side of the NPL market. Most other measures in the NPL Action Plan will also have an impact on NPL secondary markets. The introduction of prudential backstops would increase banks' incentive to sell NPLs. The establishment of AMCs has been historically one of the driving forces kick-starting secondary markets of NPLs, bringing in
17 In EBA’s September 2017 questionnaire, banks indicated both the lack of a market for transactions in NPLs and the length and costs of judiciary process as the most important impediment (agreement of about 55%, Question 26 for banks).
economies of scale, advantages of specialisation and improved pool valuation. 18 Functioning
AMCs can thereby help to both expand and to smooth the supply side of the NPL market.
Data standardisation and transaction platforms improve the matching process of demand for
and supply of NPLs. Measures to improve insolvency and enforcement would increase the recovery value of NPL, increasing the value for both demand and supply side. Annex 4.1
describes how the different initiatives set up in the Council Action Plan should impact on
prices and traded volumes by depicting a stylised view on demand and supply conditions on
the secondary market for NPLs.
Figure 5: Loan transactions and NPLs across selected EU Member States
a: Volumes in billion EUR b: in % of loans and NPLs
Source : COM calculations with data from EBA and various consultancies (see Annex 4.2).
Since most other measures of the NPL Action Plan will also have an impact on the secondary
market for NPL loans, the ultimate impact of this work stream depends also on the success of
the other measures in the NPL Action Plan. At the same time, the effectiveness of other
policies is questioned without a functioning secondary market for NPLs. Especially the benefits of AMC and supervisory action could become fruitless if demand for NPLs is
missing.
-
2.P ROBLEM DEFINITION
The consequence of missing or underdeveloped secondary markets for NPLs is that banks
with high NPLs have limited scope to sell them to non-banks or only at high transaction costs
leading to low prices. This holds in particular for smaller banks, which may have high NPL ratios and a strong incentive to sell, but find that search and transaction costs are overproportionally
high for smaller portfolios. 19 The prospect of low prices on loan sales means
banks may realise losses, which erodes their capital base and therefore represents a
disincentive to sell. 20
If NPLs cannot to be disposed, they stay on banks' balance sheets and require provisioning,
which reduces banks' profitability and business opportunities. NPLs also generate uncertainty
about asset quality, which decreases investors' demand and increases banks' capital costs. The overall result of both effects is reduced credit supply and higher lending rates, which tend to
18 See IMF (2015a).
19 See ESRB (2017).
20 See FSC (2017).
disproportionately affect lending to SMEs. 21 High NPLs bind bank operating resources and potentially prevent banks from carrying out more productive uses. 22 This effect is particularly material in smaller banks having less specialised staff. Moreover, the difficulty to assess the value of a bank which has a large stock of NPL on its balance sheet holds back merger and acquisition activity in the EU banking sector, often described as oversized. 23 Finally, a higher stock of NPLs on banks' balance sheets as consequence of a lack of secondary markets for NPL would mean that banks' are more exposed to financial turmoil, i.e. the risk of financial instability is higher.
2.1 What is the problem?
Despite some momentum in recent years, secondary markets for non-performing loans hardly exist in Europe. According to the SSM, euro-area Member States do not have a developed NPL market except Spain and Ireland, whose state of development is characterised as
medium. 24 Also outside the euro area, markets are small and underdeveloped in most EU
Member States except in the UK. While a genuine single market for NPLs in the EU would be difficult to realise in view of considerable cross-country differences in other relevant areas, in particular insolvency law, investors have been looking for opportunities beyond borders, i.e. some of those active first in the UK and Ireland and then in Spain, have entered the market in Italy or several CEECs.
Markets tend to be characterised by comparatively small trade volumes, a few large transactions involving a limited number of active investors, large bid-ask spreads when counterparts enter negotiations and a lack of transparency on market prices. 25 At the same time, Member States with higher loan sales recorded a stronger decline in their banks' NPL ratios (see Figure 10 and Figure 11), suggesting that secondary markets for NPL are contributing importantly to reduce NPL ratios.
Apart from data of NPLs on banks’ balance sheets recorded by banking supervisors and central banks, which represent the potential supply of NPL, there are no official statistics to track NPL markets. Banks are not obliged to reveal them to statistical offices and often have no incentive to disclose details. Some consultancies collect data of individual sales from various sources and publish their information in reports. This data is used in this Impact Assessment. Information about realised market prices is generally not available, but treated as confidential by the parties involved in the transaction. See Annex 4.2 for a discussion of data availability and quality and Box 1 in Annex 5.1 for a review of issues with the data on loan sale volumes.
21 See IMF (2015) and the references to empirical papers quoted therein. See also ESRB (2017).
22 ESRB (2017) argues that bankers have a comparative advantage in borrower relations and customer service, but not necessarily with respect to NPL resolution. Private equity and asset management firms can specialise in the operational and/or financial restructuring of viable borrowers and the maximisation of collateral value collection.
23 For a review of the channels through which NPLs impair merger and acquisitions activity, see the special feature in the ECB (2017b).
24 See SSM (2017), Table 13.
25 See FSC (2017), Chapters 4.2.3 and 8. See also Bruegel (2017).
Major consultancies point to less than EUR 120 billion of transactions in debt sales in 2016 in the EU, which corresponds to estimated EUR 100 billion NPLs sold. 26 The market overview in Annex 5.1 documents that the secondary NPL market is concentrated in the EU, with a strong clustering in four countries (ES, IE, IT and the UK) and dominance of large buyers (23% market share of the top five buyers, largely US or UK domiciled, over the last 2½
years). 27 According to market sources, prices depend strongly on the characteristics of the
underlying loans, varying from 5-10% of face value for unsecured consumer loans to 50-60% for secured (mortgage) loans. 28 Annex 5.1 reviews the existing data on market structures.
This apparent malfunctioning of the market is driven by problems of incentives for engaging in transactions and sufficient information about possible transactions that banks as sellers of NPLs and non-banks as potential buyers face. Information problem occur on both sides because the value of an NPL is difficult to establish given its dependence on the likelihood and amount borrowers will pay back, the value of any underlying collateral and the time and
effectiveness of legal or out-of-court enforcement. 29 They lead to high transaction costs. This
is visible in a high gap between prices offered and bid for NPLs, entailing disincentives for banks to sell as well as limited participation of potential investors. NPLs are not an established asset class investment funds traditionally focus on, implying that precedent their involvement they need to set up a new strategic orientation and investment mandates. A particular factor that can discourage NPL investors to enter the market is the difficulty to access third-party loan servicers. Loan servicers have been virtually absent in most EU Member States until recently. Their activity is segmented by country due to local regulations, which prevents them from realising scale economies.
Incentive problems give rise to market failures leading to high transaction costs
On both market sides, there are underlying incentive problems that lead to a wide bid-ask
spread. 30 Buyers assume, and therefore discount, the sellers' incentive to overrate the quality of the product. 31 Buyers have less information about the quality of the asset than the sellers. Exposure to such information disadvantage about the quality of the asset will be reflected in a risk premium that reduces the bid price of the prospective buyer. At the same time, the selling banks anticipate that the potential acquirer assumes that the bank is under pressure to divest the NPL portfolio. Otherwise it would keep it on its balance sheet and take the losses. In this
26 Loan sales are measured in gross book value of the loans, usually equal to the unpaid primary balance that the debtor owes to the creditor. EU transactions in 2016 were 118 billion in PWC Portfolio Advisory Group (Market update 2016Q4), EUR 108 billion in Deloitte (2017), EUR 110.5 billion by KPMG European transactions dashboard. The share of NPLs in loan sales is estimated at about 70-80%. See Annex 5.1
27 See Bruegel (2017).
28 See AFME (2017), quoting PWC data.
29 Potential buyers may anticipate that if banks have an opportunity to sell loans, they have a reduce incentives to adequately screen (prior to credit origination) and monitor (after credit origination) their borrowers.
30 A high bid-ask spread was frequently mentioned in the public consultation and is a prominent feature in the literature. See for example FSC (2017), ESRB (2017) and Bruegel (2017). EY (2017) estimated the bid-ask gap to be 20% for secured Italian NPLs.
31 For an application of the lemon problem on NPL, see ECB (2016) and ESRB (2017).
strategic setting, banks have an interest to demand a higher price than justified by the true
value of the NPL portfolio whereas investors have an incentive to understate their
preparedness to pay. 32
Negotiation about the purchase of an NPL entails significant transaction costs to agree on a price and other contractual terms, in addition to the information costs the buyer has to carry to
evaluate the NPL portfolio. The difficulty in closing the gap between bid and offered prices
and arriving on an agreed price between supplier and buyer leads to a long negotiation period and often prevents that deals are concluded. The available data reported in Figure 6 reveals
that about a quarter of the loan sales transactions initiated in 2015 and 2016 were still not
concluded in September 2017.
Figure 6: Number of loan sales transactions recorded in 2015 Figure 7: Bid and ask prices for NPLs across EU Member and 2016, Status in September 2017 State derived by a theoretical model
90 ue
DK SI
k val BE
oo 70 UK
FI
NL IE
ss b AT ro FR DE f g
o CY ES
% 50 SE
in PT
es CZ
ric LU LV IT
d p 30 MT LT
PL
Bi RO EE HU
BG SK EL
HR 10
10 30 50 70 90 Ask prices in % of gross book value
Source: COM calculations with KPMG data, which is retrieved Source: Commission calculations (see Annex 4.3). Note: from publicly available sources. The diagonal line represents a situation where the
theoretical bid and ask prices are equal. The higher the vertical difference between the data points and the diagonal line, the higher is the estimated bid-ask gap.
Since market participants do not disclose actual bid and ask prices, the gap between them can
only be estimated by means of a theoretical model that combines the main determinants of price formation on both market sides. Figure 7 shows how initial bid and ask prices could
differ across EU Member States using the model presented in Annex 5.3 The difference from
the bold 45 degree line indicates the size of the bid-ask spread.
Additional factors that influence bid and ask prices are listed in Box 2 in Annex 5.1. The other
measures in the NPL Action Plan, such as the establishment of transaction platforms or data
standardisation, would reduce transaction costs and therewith the bid-ask gap and thereby
foster demand for NPLs. They would not address the mentioned distorted incentives, which
32 The use of an advanced auction technique (Vickery method, i.e. the portfolio is awarded to bidder with the highest price, but at the second highest price offered) by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in their
auctions of NPLs can be considered evidence that the suppliers of NPL suppose that potential buyers are misrepresenting their valuations when they bid for NPLs.
lead to reluctance of banks to sell. Establishment of AMCs could also reduce transaction costs and the bid ask spread, for example through re-packaging of NPL portfolios from different banks. They could also be instrumental in re-balancing bargaining power on NPL markets, thereby addressing the incentive issue. Market structure would then be determined by few large players with market power on both demand and supply side of the market. While this may lead to higher NPL prices and lower bid-ask gap, it may also discourage market entry of further, especially smaller, investors and therewith not engineer an increase in demand for NPLs.
Limited buyers' participation and weak competition leading to lower bid prices and concentration on large NPL portfolios
Low demand for NPLs has led to small transaction volumes and low bid prices. 33 Market entry of new non-bank investors could enlarge the investor base and thereby increase demand and competitive pressure. Higher competition among NPL buyers, in turn, would increase bid prices, entailing larger incentives for banks to sell. Entry conditions for potential NPL investors are therefore a critical parameter to stimulate demand.
New entrants could come from various sources. There are third-country investment funds that target distressed debt or special situations, but not yet active in Europe. There are also smaller NPL investors in European Member States that target their home market, but refrain from acquiring loans in other Member States. Finally, there are also a few European firms that acquire NPL portfolios from various European banks, but specialise on specific asset classes (see Annex 5.1). Institutional investors such as pension funds and insurance companies are usually not active as direct market participants, but according to market sources some hold
shares in investment funds that buy NPLs. 34 Taking a standard market diagram, an increase in
the investor base would translate into higher bid prices and higher demand (see Annex 5.1). Policy measures that stimulate banks to supply NPLs or improve matching process are subject to other NPL work strands in the Action Plan (see Annex 4.1).
Foreign firms have been the largest investors in NPLs. Among the largest 10 investors in global distressed debt are 9 domiciled in the US and one in Canada (see Table A.5.1 in Annex 5.1). Broadening the potential investor base would be essential to increase demand for European NPLs. Since smaller European banks have a large exposure to NPLs, there seems to be also a mismatch in the size of NPL portfolios between what smaller banks could sell and non-bank investors currently active in the markets are interested to buy. While there are some smaller to medium-sized European investors in the market, they seem so far to be specialised on specific asset classes or Member States, and realise somewhat smaller average transaction volumes. 35
33 Bruegel (2017) lists the concentrated NPL investor base as a market failure.
34 One respondent to the public consultation argued that the direct participation of institutional investors would require NPL portfolios to become available in form of securitised products.
35 See Annex 5.2 for an overview of major firms active on the buyer side of the market.
Limited availability and limited geographical reach of loan servicers
A particular factor that can discourage NPL investors to enter the market is the difficulty to access third-party loan servicers. Many submissions to the public consultation supports the
notion that access to loan servicers is important for NPL markets to develop. 36 Member States
with high NPL volumes and relatively vivid loan sales such as IE, IT and ES have on average more loan servicers whereas in some other Member States such as FR and AT, loan sales are under-proportional and loan servicers play little role (see Annex 5.2).
Loan servicers take care of the "after-sale services", they administer the interest payments of debtors, collect the principal, send notices and conduct other activities that affect the recovery value of NPLs. They have a particular role in the administration of NPL portfolios once these are sold, because it is important for the buyer of an NPL portfolio to exclude the originating
bank from the debt collection to take full ownership and resolve any possible moral hazard. 37
See Box 1 in Annex 5.2 for a review of the value added of loan servicers.
Most buyers of NPLs are investment funds or asset managers without loan servicing capacity. Their expertise is in asset valuation and risk taking. They require access to third-party loan servicers for managing NPLs. Since loan servicers request a fee for doing so, 38 high costs for loan servicing are a potentially important deterrent for non-bank investors to acquire NPLs.
Facilitating the expansion of loan servicers across borders would allow them to tap scale economies, compete for business and provide their services to NPL investors at lower prices. Loan servicers have been virtually absent in most EU Member States until recently. 39 Despite dynamic adjustment in the sector in the last two years, activity has remained fragmented along
national lines. 40 Loan servicers are segmented by country, due to local regulations, and by
asset class. It is known from the US market that loan servicing benefits from scale effects,
which implies that small loan servicers are less efficient. 41 Though based on a small number
of observations and subject to a number of methodological caveats, Figure 8 suggests that third-country loan servicers active in the EU are on average larger and more profitable.
36 See reply to question 16 in Annex 2.
37 See Box 2 for an account of the advantages and disadvantages of employing independent loan servicing companies.
38 About 0.5-1.5% per annum of the exposure managed according to market sources. See Annex 5.2.
39 Annex 5.2 gives an overview of activity and market structures.
40 This notion is strongly supported by the replies to the public consultation (see Annex 2).
41 See Federal Reserve Board et al. (2016) and Annex 5.2.
Figure 8: Size and profitability of firms offering loan servicing in the EU
Source: Commission calculations with individual firm data derived from Orbis or company accounts.
See Annex 5.2.
Figure 9: Problem Tree
High entry costs from authorisation requirements in some
s Member States
Different legal provisions Limited buyers' participation
Buyer regarding loan disposal and NPL and weak competition leading resolution across Member States to low bid prices and
concentration on large NPL
Different borrower rights and legal portfolios Slow development of NPL
requirements for privacy and data markets, few transactions
rs High entry costs from licensing requirements and other obligations Limited availability of loan ther policy measures to a n ice in some Member States servicers, limited tackle NPLs become less
Lo rv geographical reach and little effective se High costs of cross-border
expansion from different licensing scope to realise scale
requirements and other obligations economies Large share of NPLs
across Member States remain on bank balance sheets, restrain lending to
Low price transparency and
ing information asymmetries
the economy High transaction costs in NPL sales
a tch Lack of market infrastructure Risks to financial stability
M Insufficient supervisory from banks with high
pressure for NPL resolution NPLs ratios
Low willingness for NPL
s Tax disincentives
disposal, high ask prices
ler Accounting treatment of Beyond the scope
Sel NPLs
2.2 What are the problem drivers?
The public consultation and a questionnaire sent to EU Member States about rules pertaining
to NPL investors and loan servicers in their jurisdiction helped identify factors that discourage participation and limit incentives to conduct cross-border activity (see Annexes 2 and 6).
High entry costs from authorisation requirements for loan purchases in some Member States
Entry conditions are a critical parameter to augment the investor base for NPLs, to increase competitive pressure and thereby kick-start market development. 42 In several Member States, non-banks are required to have authorisation from a public body if they purchase loans from banks. Especially where a full banking license (as opposed to other more specific licensing requirements) and a physical presence in the Member State concerned are required this represent costly entry barriers for potential NPL buyers in some Member States. 43 Motivation for authorisation requirements in some cases is based on debtor or data protection concerns, in others on a definition of bank activity that includes factoring services, or links holding of a loan portfolio to credit creation. Significant compliance costs seem also due if the NPL
purchase requires the establishment of a securitisation vehicle or investment firm. 44 Other
costly barriers relate to registration in each Member State they want to be active in, administrative delays and limitations on the loans they are allowed to acquire. 45 Non-EU institutions face the same requirements as EU-domiciled investors in most, but not all,
Member States. 46 (see Annex 6).
Table 1: Entry conditions for NPL investors
Banking license or authorisation from central bank or supervisor BG, EL, CY, HU, LT*, MT, AT, PT*, SI, SK+,
Authorisation from other institution DK, RO
Different authorisation for performing and NPL BG, FR, LT, PT, RO, SK Need to employ authorised loan servicers or specific structure DE, IE, EL, IT, PL, SI+,UK (SPV, AIF) Investment in NPL constrained for some types of investment BE, BG, ES, HU, FI funds * for performing household loans, ** for performing loans, + for consumer credit For more details, see Annex 6 and Appendix 6.A.3
Entry costs differ depending on firm characteristics and Member State (see Annex 3.2 and the Box in the Annex). Market sources describe them as not insurmountable, though scarcity of data and large variation in the few observations made available to Commission services do not allow an in-depth assessment. Costs to obtain authorisation are estimated to be below EUR 100,000 in most cases, unless a banking license or a securitisation vehicle is required. For example, if a NPL investor can perform under the regulatory regime of an investment
42 ESRB (2017) confirms the importance of entry costs and time and suggests activity around these lines would be rewarding.
43 In some Member States only entities holding banking licenses are allowed to buy NPLs, including CY, SI (for consumer loans), and DE (where further loan drawings may be involved). In others, like ES (for mortgage loans) and HU, only financial entities are allowed to buy NPLs. In RO, investors have to be authorized by the domestic Consumer Protection Authority and in DK, they need to be licensed debt collectors. In IT, investors are able to invest in NPL portfolios only through a local SPV supervised by the national authority.
44 Examples flagged in the public consultation refer to alternative investment fund management structures in PL, securitisation vehicles in IT.
45 The time required to obtain a license varies from 1 month to maximum 12 months, according to Member States information (Annex 6.1).
46 In Germany, non-EU investors investing in NPL are required to establish a local German servicing enterprise.
fund, the regulatory start-up costs would range between about EUR 10,000 to about EUR 15,000. 47
In addition to the actual compliance costs in monetary terms, authorisation and licencing procedures entail additional economic costs because they require potential market entrants to acquire legal expertise to understand and fulfil obligations. 48 Taking the investment fund industry as a benchmark, a recent Commission study suggests that direct regulatory fees could amount to less than 20% of the regulatory start-up costs, about 40% of the regulatory start-up costs might be attributable to compliance costs in terms of labour costs and another
approximate 40% to pay external servicers for local facilities in the host country. 49 Market
sources interviewed by the Commission assessed the average of total costs to enter a new NPL market at about EUR 60,000 to 100,000. Hence, compliance costs are deemed not particularly high in relation with total entry costs incurred by investment firms.
Different legal provisions regarding loan disposal and NPL resolution across Member States
A further obstacle to market entry stems from the legal differences and the uncertainty this creates for the loan acquirer about their rights with respect to loan enforcement from the ultimate debtor. 50 See Table 1 for an overview of specific provisions in EU Member States. The European Commission’s survey revealed that while all Member States allow the transfer of a loan, the legal instrument is different as it either entails the transfer of the credit rights or the transfer of the loan contract. Hence, entry and conduct rules for investors willing to buy NPLs differ across EU Member States and in some Member States by type of loan, implying that investors' interest to buy and therewith banks' ability to sell NPLs is fragmented across
Member States and also by asset class. 51
Differences in the legal framework entail additional costs for investors active on different national markets. They mean potential foreign NPL non-bank investors need to identify and respect the relevant licensing requirements and compliance costs in each Member State they want to be active in. Moreover, loan acquirers need to adapt their business model to each legal framework, which implies that for each Member State where they want to buy NPLs they have to develop an idiosyncratic approach for the valuation of loans, their relationship with the debtor, the procedures to enforce loans and other parts of their business conduct.
47 European Commission (2017), Impact Assessment: Initiative cross-border distribution of investment funds.
48 See Annex 3.2 for an overview of costs and their determinants.
49 European Commission (2017), Impact Assessment: Initiative cross-border distribution of investment funds.
50 This includes inter alia access to collateral, out-of-court enforcement and court rulings.
51 For example, only financial institutions are eligible creditors to floating mortgages and financial collateral in ES. Licensing of third parties for loan purchase is necessary for selling NPL consumer loans SI while for the sale of NPL corporate loans, there are information restrictions.
Table 2: Different requirements to business activity of NPL investors across EU Member States
Debtors consent required, OPUC BE, SI*, SK, No transfer of consumer credit loans, OPUC BG Restrictions on transfer of collateral, OPUC CY, UK Mandatory notification required BG, CZ*, DE*, EE, EL, IE*, HR, CY, HU, PT, SK, FI Specific loan form for transfer of the loan or the collateral LV, LT, HU*, SI Notarial certification and registration general practice or BE, BG, CZ, DK, DE, IE, ES, FR, required for the transfer of some assets AT, PT, SI Specific requirements for some loans BE, DE, AT, SI, SK, , Transferor requires authorisation from supervisory BE, DK*,HR, LV, LT*, HU*, AT* authority Banks retain responsibility if loan is transferred to entities CZ, LT, MT, SK not subject to bank secrecy Banks are not totally discharged from data protection EE, PT, SI responsibility Transfer of confidential data restricted, OPUC BG, AT * for specific loans or cases OPUC := overriding possible under conditions
Source: Member State information, see Annex 6.1.
The costs for NPL investors that the fragmentation of legal frameworks across Member States entails could be a reason why about 75% of the investors that bought NPL portfolios in 2015 and 2016 did so in only one Member State (see Table in Annex 5.1). The replies to the public consultations reveal that stakeholders consider the legal framework, insolvency rules and local habits as obstacles for cross-border activity. Some respondents also referred to data issues or incentive problems as factors (see Annex 2).
A cost estimate of the impact of these factors is not possible given the lack of data and strong differences across Member States. Information from market sources suggests that costs for supervisory reporting, internal audit, risk compliance, credit management procedures and antimoney laundering differ substantially across firms. A common pattern is that costs for compliance with anti-money laundering legislation are sizeable, which is in line with the prominence of know-your-customers concerns in the replies to the public consultation.
High entry costs from licensing requirements and other obligations for loan servicers in some Member States
Loan servicers are exposed to challenges similar to NPL investors with respect to authorisation and licensing. Regulatory entry barriers are more widespread across Member States than those for NPL investors and often motivated by debtor and data protection considerations. For this reason, some Member States even request physical presence in the Member State. The request for authorisation and domiciliation in particularly allows supervision by domestic authorities. Since restructuring of a loan can entail new lending, some Member States request from loan servicers to obtain a banking license. 52 Some Member States also insist that NPL investors make use of loan servicers that are licensed and
supervised by their authorities (See Annex 6 ) 53 . Non-EU loan servicers are permitted in all
Member States, except one. 54
Table 3: Entry conditions for loan servicers
Banking license DE*, FR**, HU, MT**, AT, RO**, SK
Authorisation from central bank or supervisor EL, IE, NL*, PT, UK
Authorisation from other institution DK, SE, FI, IT, LV, LU
Restrictions on debt enforcement BG, DK
-
*depends on decision of supervisor, ** if activity covers lending or refinancing.
For more details, see Annex 6 and Appendix 6.A.3.
While fees for obtaining a license vary across Member States, they are overall small compared to overall entry costs loan servicers face, estimated to amount to EUR 5-15
million. 55 From the limited information the Commission services were able to obtain, one-off
fees for the licensing range from a few hundred to more than EUR 50,000. Annual licencing fees vary significantly as well, ranging from a few hundred euro per annum to more than EUR 30,000. Compliance costs for data reporting could add to these set-up and licencing fees as well as the costs to comply with anti-money laundering rules that may prove significant.
High costs of cross-border expansion from different licensing requirements and other obligations for loan servicers across Member States
Cross border expansion can help loan servicers to grow and realise scale effects, thereby allowing them to offer lower prices for NPL investors. Since this requires multiple authorisation processes and adjustment of the business models to national conditions, cross border expansion is made more costly by differences in licensing and conduct rules across Member States. Loan servicing activities primarily fall under the freedom of contract, and there are no formal legal definitions of 'servicing', 'managing' and/or 'debt collection' of loans in most Member States. The resulting legal uncertainty about definitions applied in other Member States could be a reason why few loan servicers pursue cross-border expansion strategies. Reduction of legal uncertainty by the adoption of legislation that governs the establishment of loan servicing firms, as part of the country's economic adjustment programmes, has been instrumental in fostering the market in Ireland. Comparable legislation
52 In almost all Member States, servicers do need to comply with certain fit-and-proper requirements. In IE and EL, servicers are required to comply with specific requirements and only entities that have an appropriate licence can conduct credit servicing. In LV, a provider of debt recovery services requires a special license. In DE, FR, HU and AT, they require a restricted banking license.
53 For example, NPL investors can acquire loans in EL only under the condition that they have signed a loan management agreement with a servicing company properly licensed and supervised by the Bank of Greece. In DE, non-EU investors investing in NPL are required to establish a local German servicing enterprise.
54 In EL, non-EU loan servicers are not permitted and non-Greek EU loan servicers must act through a branch. In AT, in case of pure outsourcing, stricter requirements can apply especially with regard to data protection issues.
55 ESRB (2017) quotes market information for this estimate.
has also been adopted in Greece and has led to the establishment of loan servicing firms in that country very recently. 56
A specific point to loan servicers is how their relationship with non-bank NPL investors is governed, which entails possible restrictions on which services they are allowed to offer to the latter. There are no explicit prerequisites that a creditor has to satisfy before outsourcing certain servicing functions unless outsourcing is deemed to affect core functions or services in almost all Member States. However, loan monitoring and refinancing, which are typical byproducts of loan servicing are considered a core services in some Member States. 57 In this case, outsourcing to loan servicers is not allowed or tied to strict requirements. Moreover, the creditor cannot outsource the undertaking formal enforcement actions in the large majority of Member States, i.e. investor-linked servicers are not permitted to undertake such actions on the creditor’s behalf.
The variation in licensing costs across Member States referred to above can serve as an approximation of the entry burden to loan servicing markets. In the absence of direct cost estimates, evidence that they have a material impact can be derived from the observation that as regards cross-border entry or expansion of loan servicers, the most frequent approach in the last years has been the acquisition of existing national loan servicers, implying that expansion to a new market is difficult without national incumbents already being present.
Different borrower rights and legal requirements for privacy and data
Respondents to the public consultation stress data and information problems to be a major obstacle to the acquisition of NPLs. Restrictions on non-bank investors are motivated by concerns about bank secrecy and personal data protection. These restrictions impair the transfer of information from the bank to the non-bank investor. This, in turn, complicates the evaluation of the value of the loan portfolio before the sale is signed, i.e. the potential buyer has only access to limited and anonymised information from which he needs to assess the recovery value of the NPL and, to the extent loans are collateralised, the value of the underlying collateral. The existing fragmentation among Member States of rules on data protection renders data management by non-bank investors more difficult in case they aim administer loans from different jurisdictions at a central place in order to realise scale effects. 58
Bank secrecy provisions generally contain an exemption that allows the bank to disclose data which are necessary and proportionate for selling the loan. The FISMA survey unveiled legal constraints in a number of Member States. For example, the transfer of confidential data is only allowed under the debtor's consent or an authority's decision in a few Member States (see Annex 6). Despite possible constraints from privacy and personal data protection, banks as sellers and non-banks and buyers have found ways to cope with them, for example by
56 A first loan servicing firm was authorised in July 2017.
57 See Annex 6.
58 This situation is expected to improve with the application of the General Data Protection Regulation as from May 2018 and the harmonization of data protection rules resulting therefrom.
providing anonymized or aggregated data in the pre-transaction phase. Hence, rather than making it impossible to negotiate a trade of NPLs, they increase transaction costs.
Cross-border transactions could entail conflict of laws. For example if an NPL purchasers from a different Member State than the originating bank and the borrower sells the loan on to a further NPL purchaser in another country. The latter may then question which national law applies, especially if the NPL purchaser is in a third country. For cross-border transactions in the EU, the so-called Brussels I and Rome I rules apply. In case of a third country and of a borrower that is a consumer, the consumer law and jurisdiction should, in principle, also apply but the situation would need to be assessed on a case by case basis taking also into account the third country rules on conflict of laws. Therefore, parties to a cross-border transfer of loans have to do their due diligence based on a set of potentially applicable laws. This inflates the costs of legal opinions required for due diligence 59 .
Borrower rights, in particular consumer rights, are different across Member States and also defined via different legal means, e.g. through insolvency regimes, borrower and consumer protection laws, or authorisation and supervision procedures. These rights do not change with
the transfer of a loan from a bank to a third party. 60 However, the legal protection of
borrowers' rights might be affected if the transfer of the loan modified the contractual relationship, if it led to a change of applicable law to a different country's law, or if it became subject to a different regime of general rules on debtors' protection. This could be problematic, in particular, for debts referred to consumers. Both NPL investors and loan servicers therefore need to adjust their business models to the legal regime in each Member State they want to be active in. Table 2 lists a number of rules that NPL investors and loan servicers have to adhere to in the different Member States. The existence of various countryspecific legal requirements implies that a single market for NPLs in the EU will still remain segmented along national lines even if authorisation and conduct rules for NPL investors and loan servicers are standardised.
Differences in borrower rights across the Single Market motivate authorisation processes for NPL investors and loan servicers in some Member States. For example, IE and EL explicitly request compliance with borrower protection rules in their laws that authorise loan servicers, SE mandates the authorisation process to the data protection authority. Other Member States may not explicitly require a license out of the motivation to safeguard borrower rights or personal data protection. Registration and licensing, nevertheless, gives them an opportunity to monitor and/or supervise behaviour of the firm, therewith act if compliance with national law is jeopardised.
Are the problem drivers significant?
Policy makers have control over regulatory costs, such as direct costs of obtaining an authorisation to do business, and indirect costs that emerge from rules that govern the conduct
59 The Commission undertook a public consultation on the conflict of laws rules for third party effects of transactions in securities and claims in 2017.
60 For example, recital 41 of the Consumer Credit Directive 2008/48 i states: "assignment should not have the effect of placing the consumer in a less favourable position.
of business and may limit profit opportunities. While the rules in place determine costs of compliance for market entrants, not all entry costs can be influenced through policy measures. An important fixed-cost component in the entry decision of the NPL investor is the due diligence that has to be performed on any NPL portfolio targeted. Moreover, potential entrants need to invest in studying local legal conditions that determine the recover value of the loans as well as the legal rights and obligations they would have as loan owners.
The replies to the public consultation suggest that a large share of the respondents considers an EU framework helpful and that licensing rules should be part of it (see Annex 2). While market sources indicated that regulatory costs are not their main concern when deciding to enter NPL and loan servicing markets, this suggests that regulatory costs are not an insignificant part of entry costs.
Even if these regulatory costs may not be high in absolute terms, their impact on entry decisions is amplified by:
expanding the disadvantage vis-à-vis incumbent market players that already benefit from
an information advantage from past experiences. Entry decisions are surrounded by uncertainty and complex interactions among a multitude of relevant factors. Most importantly, entry costs have the character of sunk costs, i.e. they are foregone and not reversible if the plan to enter the market is aborted or the activity turns out not to be sufficiently profitable. Since it is uncertain that a deal with a bank can be closed, the sunk cost character of entry investments has a significant impact on the decision to enter NPL
markets.
becoming recurring for each national market that the investor wants to enter or expand to.
Regulatory costs and different national rules undermine the possibility of NPL investors to enter smaller markets and of loan servicers to realise scale effects. They especially increase search costs if either of the two considers expanding activity to another Member State. The different legal rules across EU Member States may also discourage particularly foreign investors to enter EU markets, for example US investment funds that are used to face uniform rules and try to realise scale economies from conducting large transactions.
For example, scale economies are well documented for US loan servicers. 61
translating into search costs required to find out what regulatory requirements and related
costs actually are, which again increases with each national market the investor wants to enter. The latter two are particularly important for foreign investors. In the NPL market, entry costs entail search costs, compliance costs, costs for advise on legal and administrative matters. Investors active in the NPL market report that costs to understand
local conditions and the relevant legislation matter importantly.
Other problem drivers
It should also be noted that the public consultation revealed a number of further factors, which stakeholders consider important to foster activity on NPL and loan servicing markets, and
61 See Federal Reserve Board et al. (2016) and Annex 5.2.
which are not addressed here. Stakeholders also often stressed the impact of harmonised insolvency frameworks and improved debt enforcement as relevant for the development of secondary markets. Access to data is also an important factor for potential buyers in order to assess the value of an NPL portfolio. Market sources often refer to a lack of supply of NPLs from banks. These are subject of other work strands of the Action Plan, addressing specifically, a review of national insolvency frameworks, templates for standardised data through which banks facilitate buyers’ evaluation of loan portfolios and means to establish a transaction platform. Taxation was also repeatedly listed. An obvious point is that banks are exempted from VAT while loan servicers are liable to VAT. Annex 6.2 summarises obstacles to the development of secondary markets for NPLs flagged in the public consultation, including those that are subject to other work strands of the NPL Action Plan.
2.3 How will the problem evolve?
Without supportive policy measures, one could expect that the investor base in NPL grows along its past trend and that loan sales may not increase by much as compared to the level of EUR 100 to 150 billion per annum as realised in the last years. Loan sales may even decline as past activity was concentrated in a few countries, and in some of them the stock of NPL has already declined (e.g. UK, DE) whereas loan sales in some Member States with high NPL ratios would remain at the modest level realised in the past. The consequence would be that revenues from NPLs sales remain modest and the NPL stock on banks' balance sheet declines gradually.
One could assume a decline in the NPL ratio along the GDP growth path. Credit growth has been sluggish in countries with high NPL ratios. This could continue and may feed back into
relatively weaker economic growth in these countries. 62 If national markets become attractive
(for example through supervisory pressure on banks to sell NPLs or reform of insolvency law that increase recovery values) market demand could develop endogenously and when faced with high opportunity costs of non-action, Member States may adopt legislation to support this process. The cases of Ireland and Greece suggest that even if the NPL problem is recognised by policy makers as requiring action, it takes time until for example laws that govern market entry into loan servicing markets are in place.
-
3.W HY SHOULD THE EU ACT ?
3.1 Legal basis
Article 114 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) confers to the European institutions the competence to lay down appropriate provisions that have as their objective the establishment and functioning of the single market. NPL purchases are a form of capital movement under the free movement of capital principle, which is applicable to investors from third-countries like the US as well. The problem that the initiative under consideration aims to address is related to different rules in the Member States as regards the rules for third parties acquiring NPLs from banks, as well as rules for offering loan servicing
62 A recent research paper estimates that NPLs would decline significantly in Italy only if economic growth was higher than 1.2% per annum. See Mohhaddes et al (2017).
services (see Annexes 6 and 7) that restrict both the free flow of NPLs within the EU and investment opportunities for third-country investors. Consequently, the development of a single market for NPL investors and for loan servicers faces obstacles and without measures at EU level, national markets for NPLs and loan servicers will remain fragmented and in most Member States underdeveloped.
3.2 Subsidiarity: Necessity of EU action
The analytical work leading to the NPL Action Plan demonstrated that NPL ratios are currently high in a substantial number of Member States, reaching unsustainable levels in a
few cases. 63 This legacy stock of bad debt creates risks of cross-border spill-overs throughout
the EU economy and its financial system. Moreover, the high stock of NPLs alters market perceptions of the European banking sector as a whole and represents negative externalities for the whole EU. 64 These factors have become even more relevant in the context of the Banking Union. By contributing to enhanced growth and reducing financial fragmentation,
measures to address the existing stock of NPLs would be beneficial for the EU as a whole. 65
With respect to building up or expanding the investor base for NPLs, Member States have an incentive to act and reduce regulatory barriers to attract foreign investors and to facilitate domestic investors or loan servicers to enter the market. A few Member States have actively acted to address the high stock of NPLs (IE, ES, EL, PT, SI), in most cases fostered through
an EU/IMF economic adjustment programme. 66 Yet, progress in these Member States remains
slow and did not counteract the spill-overs of risk perceptions of a weakened EU banking system as a whole. Given the inability to address the issue through action at the level of individual Member States, the subsidiarity principle warrants action at EU level.
While policy measures at the national level are possible, they are likely to cement market fragmentation. IE and EL set up legislation that governs the licensing process of loan servicers. Both, however, followed different approaches: the Irish law requests compliance with light fit-and-proper criteria for the authorisation without inference on business conduct, whereas the Greek law is more demanding, requesting for example loan servicers to act through a local entity and to take care of socially vulnerable groups (see Annex 66).
63 See FSC (2017), ESRB (2017), ECB (2016, 2017).
64 This was for example evident in a decline of share prices of almost all EU banks larger than the decline in the general stock price index when EBA released stress test results in summer 2016, although the results showed large differences among participating banks and suggested little exposure to stress for a considerable number of banks. For empirical analyses on spill over in the European banking system, see European Commission (2017a) and the references therein.
65 From the EC FIN Action Plan: "The Council […] REC GNISES that although in the majority of Member States high NPL ratios did not emerge in recent years, the negative effects of current high NPL ratios in a substantial number of Member States can pose risks of cross-border spill-overs in terms of the overall economy and financial system of the EU and alter market perceptions of the European banking sector as a whole, especially within the Banking Union."
66 Progress has become visible in rising transactions in NPLs with non banks once an asset management company was set up (IE, ES, SI) to collect NPLs from banks and make them available for sale. In Italy, acute banking problems gave rise to public support measures that incentivised the sales of NPLs to nonbanks.
Stigma effects are a very likely reason why Member States have not yet taken a more active stance in reducing regulatory barriers to attract foreign investors to the NPL market. While there is no hard evidence on such factors, a number of channels may be relevant. Ultimate debtors represent a larger social group than creditors and they may see little advantage from a transfer of the ownership of their debt to foreign investors. They may even experience uncertainty if their debt is transferred from a creditor they know to an unknown third party entity and if they encounter difficulties to clarify whether or not the rules protecting them would remain valid. Since foreign hedge funds are the most visible NPL investors, their reputation as short-term oriented profit maximising entities may discourage policy makers from taking action to facilitate their operations. Legislators also strive to keep consumer protection at high levels and may fear that the transfer of NPLs to non-banks could challenge this protection. This initiative aims at addressing impediments to loan transfers, while ensuring that borrower rights in Member States are preserved.
3.3 Subsidiarity: Added value of EU action
An EU-wide framework for NPL buyers and loan servicers would help reap scale effects and reduce entry costs for firms intending to operate in different national markets. It would help overcome the coordination issue in EU NPL markets where weaknesses in demand and supply amplify each other. In particular, banks would benefit from a larger investor base since competition among investors would exert upward pressure on prices. Investors, in turn, would benefit from a unified European legal framework as it would reduce their entry costs and create more favourable conditions and infrastructure for their cross-border operations.
Under an EU framework for loan servicers, firms' activity would be less constrained by the size of the domestic market. Consequently, expansion to other markets would allow loan servicing companies to grow in size and to realise scale effects, and potentially charge lower fees to NPL investors. Moreover, NPL purchasers would no longer be required to build a new relationship with a loan servicer in each market, but they would be able to work with a loan servicer they worked with in other Member States.
So far, debt servicers and investors concentrate on a handful of national markets, probably those with highest profit margins. In order to reap opportunities in other markets, they need to acquire expertise about prevailing local regulation and about the availability of loan servicing firms. While these search and compliance costs may not be very high, they still represent an effective obstacle to entry if the target market is small.
Developing an EU-wide investor base for NPLs would also be key for the effectiveness of other measures in the NPL Action Plan since the efficiency of asset management companies in coordinating NPL supply, of bank supervision in earmarking NPLs, information templates to standardise information on NPLs depends on the potential demand for NPLs.
Measures at EU level would also be beneficial to overcome the stigma effects that Member States face when pursuing legislative changes at national level in this area. 67 However, these
67 Ireland and Greece, which stand out as Member States that initiated legislation on loan servicers, did so as part of programme conditionality.
measures should not decrease the level of consumer protection, as the negative consequences of such a decrease could entail social and financial costs that might outweigh the possible benefits.
-
4.O BJECTIVES : W HAT IS TO BE ACHIEVED ?
A first general objective of the NPL package is to limit risks to financial stability by reducing the stock of NPLs in the European banking system and by avoiding the build-up of NPLs in the EU banking system in the future. A second general objective of NPL reduction is the support of stable financing to the economy and therewith economic growth. Banks saddled with NPLs tend to face higher funding costs and capital requirements and lower profitability, which limits their ability to extend new credit. Persistently weak loan portfolios are thus a potential drag on financing of firms, households and ultimately economic growth. Functioning secondary markets for NPL would allow banks to sell NPLs to non-banks, thereby reducing risks of financial stability and liberate resources to expand lending to the economy.
The first specific objective of this initiative is to stimulate demand for NPLs by generating a larger investor basis, and consequently also greater competition among investors. Greater demand for NPLs and greater competition among investors is expected to contribute to both a higher volume of NPL transactions and higher bid prices on secondary markets. This should contribute to reducing NPLs in banks’ balance sheets, thereby enhancing banks' resilience, and ultimately improving lending to the economy as well as reducing risks to financial stability. While the immediate objective is to decrease the presently high level of NPLs in the EU and some of its Member States in particular, a larger participation of buyers on NPL markets will also be beneficial in case of future accumulation of NPLs on banks' balance sheets.
Mirroring an increase in buyers' participation on NPL markets, a second specific objective consists in a complementary increase in the capacity of loan servicing firms to absorb rising demand for their servicers from more loan sales by NPL investors. Demand would be most efficiently matched if prices for loan servicing are competitive and geographical reach expands to all Member States.
More specifically, to strengthen the demand side and competition on these markets, the initiative aims at: (i) facilitating market entry of NPL investors and loan servicers in MS with high NPLs and material obstacles to market entry, (ii) fostering the entry of smaller firms so that smaller banks have a higher chance of finding counterparts in NPL transactions, (iii) equal treatment across markets in Member States, allowing loan servicers to realise scale economies from cross-border operation, (iv) enhancing competition through the entry of foreign firms. The first two items could be considered as means to address failure in (national) NPL markets, whereas the latter three may be instrumental in fostering a single NPL market.
The investor base would be largest if a single market was created, so that investors would not discriminate across conditions on various national markets, and if conditions would be supportive to foreign firms' market entry. The objective of a genuine single market seems very ambitious given the importance of national and local determinants on NPL markets. Still it would be desirable that both domestic and foreign investors can expand activity across borders as easily as possible, so as to come close to a shared investor base among all EU Member States. Harmonised licensing and conduct rules could deliver this. The same could be accomplished by converging rules at national level. This would result in increased transactions of NPLs, eventually leading to a reduction of NPLs in banks.
More competition on loan servicing markets should result in lower costs charged by loan servicers to NPL holders and create profit opportunities through lower administrative costs and/or allowing synergy effects with other business areas. Creating wider profit margins through lower administrative costs and/or allowing synergy effects with other business areas should also lead to higher preparedness to pay for NPL investors, implying a pass through to prices that banks can realise when they offer their NPL portfolio.
Changes to entry conditions for loan purchasers and loan servicers could change the relationship between borrower and creditor and their negotiation position, especially since the transfer of the loan entails that the borrower faces a new counterpart that she/he had not chosen and possibly not even known. If this new counterpart is located or authorised in a different Member State, the borrower may consider these rights undermined, even if the contractual obligations of the new creditor remain unchanged. It is therefore also an objective of the initiative (v) to ensure efficient supervision and (vi) adequate safeguards for borrower rights. This would require, in particular, that the borrower protection clauses of the original contract are fully maintained even in case the contractual terms are modified as a result of the transfer the loan and that the general set of consumer protection rules in force in the country of the debtor is fully maintained and adequately enforced even in the case the debt servicer operates in regime of passport.
It would be problematic if purchasers of NPL were outside the scope of existing data protection rules. Acquisition of NPL by non-EU funds will imply either a transmission of data (if the acquirer processes the data in the EU) or a transfer of data (if he processes them in a third country) from the banks to the acquirer. In both cases the rules of the General Data Protection Regulation (GDPR) apply with particular reference to rules on international transfers in the latter case. Since GDPR provides maximum harmonisation, Member States cannot raise protection standards. Since the GDPR contains a number of "opening clauses" which allow Member States to further specify its rules and since there might be differences between Member States' approaches to its implementation, there is a potential for downgrading of the actual protection data receives if the new data controller is in a different country. Such a downgrade would be avoided if the acquirer of the credit had to respect the personal data protection prevailing in the country of the borrower.
-
5.W HAT ARE THE AVAILABLE POLICY OPTIONS ?
5.1 Framing the policy options' features
Entry and business conditions for both potential NPL buyers and loan servicers currently vary across Member States, as described in Section 2.2 and in Annex 6. This situation can be improved through various channels, such as simplifying and reducing cross-country variation of authorisation and licensing procedures and reducing administrative barriers and crosscountry variation in information sharing rules, etc. This section defines a set of dimensions with available alternative policy choices. This framing of policy features will subsequently be used to define the policy options.
Authorisation procedures for loan purchasers
The entry conditions for loan investors often take the form of an authorisation procedure by National Competent Authorities (NCAs). One of the main divergences among Member States is whether or not a banking licence is required for loan purchasers. A lighter authorisation procedure would rely only on fit-and proper criteria (e.g., good repute of directors, to consider capital requirements or professional insurance, organisational requirements on IT, risk control, internal audit, compliance office). The authorisation requirement for purchasers can be partially or fully waived in cases where the loan purchase is registered with a NCA and the loan is serviced by an authorised servicer. Different setups are possible as regards crossborder activity of loan purchasers (national authorisation, passporting, single authorisation, etc.).
Business rules for loan purchasers
Rules applicable to the activity of loan investors may stipulate whether some types of transfers are restricted or require additional authorisations. As regards the resolution of NPLs, restrictions may apply for loan purchasers with respect to rescheduling of the original loans (in some Member States a banking licence is required). Member States have different legal instruments to transfer loans and a number of civil law provisions that may impose constraints on what NPL purchasers can undertake, for example if debtors are in insolvency procedures. Making these subject to harmonisation appears not proportional and is therefore not considered part of the option set.
Scope of eligible loans
The set of loans non-banks are allowed to buy differ among Member States. While a few do not have any limitations, some, e.g. BG, FR, LT, PT, RO, SK have different rules for nonperforming and performing loans. The purchase of consumer credit loans is not possible in BG while also BE, LT, NL, SI and SK have special protection for household loans or consumer credit. While the main public interest is in enabling the purchase of non-performing loans, it is difficult to control in practice because most loans are sold in large portfolios. Some of these portfolios contain both performing and non-performing loans.
While their interest in maintaining a customer relationship with performing borrowers creates an incentive for banks to limit purchases to non-performing loans, actual sales often include sales that do not fall under the formal definition of non-performing. This includes: Some loans are expected to become non-performing, others may be partly performing, some may be performing, but from debtors that did not service other loans, etc. Part of the wider market for loan sales are also loans supplied by public asset management companies as consequence of
the wind up of credit institutions. 68 The actual share of non-performing loans in loan sales is
unknown; the estimations shown in Annex 4.2 suggest it could be between 70 and 80%. The counterpart of about a third of NPLs on banks' balance sheet are households and the share of
loan sales owed by consumers was at least 11% in 2015-16. 69
68 For example, one of the largest sales in 2017 related to a portfolio by UK asset manager UKAR and compromised a face value of 11.8 billion GBP in 104000 performing loans that originated from Bradford and Bingley before the banks was taken in public ownership in 2010. See http://www.ukar.co.uk/media-centre/press-releases/2017/31-03-2017?page=4 .
69 See Annex 5.1.
Authorisation procedures for loan servicers
Similarly to loan investors, the authorisation procedure for loan servicers may or may not be linked to a banking licence requirement. Alternatively, the authorisation may merely rely on a fit-and-proper check (as in the case of investors: repute of directors, capital requirements or professional insurance, IT requirements, risk control, audit, and compliance). Cross-border activity of loan servicers can also be subject to different regulatory setups (national licensing, passporting, single authorisation, etc.).
Business rules for loan servicers
The scope of activity of loan servicers may be more or less broad. It usually includes such activities as direct contact with the debtor, but may in some cases go as far as out-of-court or judicial recovery. Again, servicers' role in rescheduling re-payment of the loan may require modifications in some Member States, in order to clarify whether a banking license is required in this context. Rules on outsourcing of activities can state whether the outsourcing institution maintains responsibility and accountability. Similarly to above, loan servicers' activity will be constrained by national rules, for example on debtor protection, which will continue to be set at the Member States' level.
Protection of debtor rights, privacy and data protection
An important challenge of this policy initiative is the potential conflict with debtor rights
protection and personal data protection laws. 70 Some Member States set specific conditions or
limit the scope of business activity for loan purchasers and loan servicers, others govern these issues in other laws, independent from the authorisation process of these entities, or impose the same rules on banks and loan servicers. In particular, the transfer of loans could cause issues with personal data protection if the processing of data involved in the change of creditor is carried out in non-compliance with data protection rules. If the debtor becomes subject to an insolvency procedure, NPL investors have very different rights and obligations in the different Member States. Since the issue of insolvency and debtor protection is covered in a different NPL work stream, this Impact Assessment discusses the effects in terms of gaps that could emerge if licensing and conduct rules for NPL investors and loan servicers are changed. Member States that currently use authorisation procedures as a means to ensure debtor rights protection may need to enact new legislation to maintain the desired level of protection through other means, e.g. through adopting more specific borrower protection rules. 71
Since changes to the authorisation regime of NPL purchasers and loan servicers could interfere with borrower rights, additional safeguards for the borrower could be warranted, in particular as regards consumers. As a matter of principle, borrower protection rules stemming from the contractual relationship as well as from legislation in the borrower's home country
70 The Consumer Credit Directive has an explicit recital that assignment of credit does not change the defences a borrower had available against the original creditor, 2008/48/EC.
71 A benchmarking exercise, dedicated peer review by Member States, country specific recommendations focusing on insolvencies issues in the European Semester.
should be maintained. In addition, these risks could also be mitigated by introducing a requirement of notification of the debtor about the change of creditor, as well as about the applicability of national and EU rules on debtor rights protection and civil law rules about loan contracts. It could also be envisaged to strengthen supervision of the entities' actual conduct to further ensure safeguarding borrowers' rights. As regards cross-border operations of NPL purchasers and servicers, administrative cooperation mechanisms for NCAs and dedicated contact points for debtor appeals located in the debtor's Member State of the debtor should also be part of the policy initiative.
5.2 Identified regulatory best practices
The different elements described above need to be combined in a consistent way, yielding a regulatory regime that would be on average lighter and more comparable across Member States. Since it is neither proportionate nor feasible in the short-to-medium run to amend parameters such as civil law and insolvency regime, they represent the external context (which will be a given) to the conduct of NPL purchasers and loan servicers in a new regulatory regime. Additional safeguards for borrowers may be required depending on the other modifications brought by the new regulatory regime. The following list identifies regulatory best practices in a number of areas. These could constitute building blocks for a consistent new regulatory regime.
Licensing requirements for investors: In terms of making market access easier for NPL investors, one approach is to not foresee licensing requirements at national level (e.g. currently in CZ, ES, HR, LV, FI). Application of this principle to all EU Member States could potentially undermine the debtor protection specifically targeted by the rules in some Member States. A compromise solution is a lighter authorisation requirement for NPL investors, using a fit-and proper approach (e.g. IE and PT use such an approach for loan servicers, see below). Such authorisation requirement allows checking whether the applicant fulfils certain general conditions when it enters the market (see examples of fit-and-proper criteria in the previous section). Beyond the usefulness of the criteria themselves to ensure a certain level of quality and protection in the market, a light authorisation regime has the merit of establishing a first contact with the supervisor. This enables the supervisor to check, to review and, if necessary, to sanction the conduct of the entity. With respect to preserving the current level of debtor rights, lighter authorisation would therefore be consistent with a stronger role of the supervisor in controlling conduct.
Use of loan servicers by investors: Some Member States have close to no specific obligation on NPL investors, but require the use of an authorised loan servicer (IE, EL). Since most NPL investors delegate debt collection to loan servicing companies, which are the only ones to get in direct contact with the debtor, this requirement does not seem to lead to disproportionate costs. Since the outsourcing mandate to a loan servicer should not discharge the NPL investor from its responsibilities, rules need to clarify obligations and define how the investor monitors the loan servicer. Therefore, the licensing requirements, as discussed in the previous paragraph, could be less stringent where the NPL investor relies on an authorised servicer. If the NPL investor performs the loan servicing itself, the rules for both loan investors and servicers (if different) need to apply to it.
Types of loans eligible for disposal: Several Member States make a distinction between loan purchasers acquiring performing or non-performing loans (BG, FR, LT, PT, RO, SK) or have special rules for loans owed by households (BG and to some extent BE, LT, NL, SI and SK). Other Member States do not make this eligibility distinction. In Member States that have different rules for the sale of performing and non-performing loans this distinction tends to lead to higher transaction costs and lower interest of investors. This may be a cause of relatively low contribution of loan sales to the decline in NPLs during the period 2015-16 in BG and PT and the absence of notable loan sales in FR. 72 The reason why some Member States have different rules is that they consider ownership of a performing loan as similar to credit granting and therefore see a need to regulate them comparable to banks. This means that such investors are required to hold a banking license. The purchase and administration of loans, however, technically does not generate new credit. Moreover, non-bank investors do not refinance themselves through deposits and hence should not be subject to the same supervision or same restrictions on leverage or minimum capital as credit institutions. In economic terms, holding and administration of an existing loan is not similar to bank business and therefore should not necessarily require a banking license.
Apart from the cases described above, Member States do not restrict the sale of loans owed by households and instead provide protection for consumers and house owners through other means than authorisation conditions for non-bank loan purchasers or limitations on whether loans owed by consumers could be sold. The wider the coverage of eligible NPL, the fewer potential distortions between market segments need to be considered. From the perspective of the bank, NPLs from households or corporations weigh equally on their balance sheet and limiting the possibility to sell corporate loans would reduce the NPL’s potential market size by a third. From the perspective of a household, consumer credit and mortgage credit may be of same importance and it would be up to political preferences whether one or the other requires more safeguards in case of transfer to non-banks.
Authorisation requirements for servicers: Some Member States request authorisation of loan servicers along a fit-and-proper approach (IE, PT). They are in direct contact with the debtors and supervisors need to ensure that they comply with relevant rules relative to debtor protection, privacy and data protection. Although a few Member States do not have specific licensing requirements for loan servicing firms, such an approach might not be advisable at EU level due to the possible effects on the debtor rights. Due to risks for financial stability and importance of debtor protection, there is a strong interest to ensure that servicing firms have the organisational and technical capacity to operate in accordance with applicable laws and that they can continue business even against economic or legal headwinds. Hence, fulfilment of organisational requirements and possibly even request for indemnity insurance or loss absorbance capacity seems useful. Similar to the treatment of NPL purchasers, a lighter authorisation regime for servicers could be balanced by stronger supervisory rights.
Loss coverage of servicers: Most Member States do not request minimum capital for loan servicers. However, BG, EL and RO do and in some other Member States minimum capital requirements may emerge as consequence of the need to hold a banking license. In order to reflect the fact that loan servicers' activity is much narrower than that of credit institutions, it would be advisable to not subject them to capital requirements applicable to credit institutions. In order to secure that firms are able to compensate any damages related to their
72 See Figure 5b or Figures A.4.4 and A.4.5 in Annex 4.
operations, one could consider a requirement of either indemnity insurance, or a capital buffer.
Borrower rights: Very often purchasers of NPLs are from a different Member State than the borrower or even from outside the EU. 73 In order to avoid that the cross-border transfer of a loan leads to uncertainty about which Member States' law applies, the standard approach is that the law that governs the contractual relationship between the borrower and the initial creditor, as well as the consumer protection rules of the borrower's home country continue to apply. This means that the borrower rights remain untouched from the transfer and the new owner cannot derive any additional rights if it is located in a country with a more creditor friendly regime. NPL purchasers and loan servicers would then need to adjust their business model and internal compliance standards to the law of the Member State of the initial loan contract, irrespective of their domicile, authorisation and passport. Currently, market participants rely primarily on consultancy firms and law firms to obtain such information. At least loan servicers set up domestic entities or cooperate with domestic firms to ensure compliance with national provisions.
Code of conduct for servicers: Ireland refers to borrower rights and to a code of conduct in its law that governs the authorisation of loan servicers. Sweden tasked its data protection authority with the authorisation of debt collection firms. Loan servicers need to observe existing legislation in Member States, especially insolvency law and borrower rights. And since they deal with personal information, they need to respect data protection laws. Other conduct rules that govern processes how they interact with debtors may also be warranted as regards their fundamental rights. If they take the form of legal obligations or enforceable codes, supervisors would be entitled to control and possibly sanction in case of misbehaviour. It is worth mentioning that some loan servicers have committed to self-set conduct rules that restrict their interactions with borrowers to certain limits, i.e. not using communication that is perceived as threatening or intrusion into privacy, or not spreading certain information. An industry association of loan servicers announced its incentive to set up conduct rules for the industry in its reply to the public consultation.
Rescheduling of loan repayment by servicers: Practice among most Member States, with notable exceptions in BG and DK, which place limits on the capacity of loan servicers in debt enforcement, is also that loan servicers can agree on rescheduling debtors' repayment of the loan outside insolvency proceedings. Often they can launch or participate in enforcement actions. It seems desirable that loan servicers do not face limitations in their efforts to reschedule the payment stream or establish a repayment plan, provided that is bilaterally agreed with the debtor. Even though this is in many regards not comparable to a new credit generation, some Member States such as AT treat it as such, which leads to a banking license requirement. Since outsourcing to external loan servicers is common practice in this business, other national practices consider that servicers' participation in debt resolution mechanisms (restructuring as well as enforcement) should not be hindered. In absence of requirements for such actions, there would, however, be a need rules ensuring that responsibility is not diluted,
73 Tables A.5.1 and A.5.2 report the geographic origin of large NPL purchasers.
especially as regards the responsibility of the loan purchasers. Beyond these NPL-related cases, loan services would be bound by existing rules at EU and national level.
Supervision and cross-border activity: Given the lack of EU competence in supervision on this matter, national competent authorities play an important role as supervisors of loan servicers. If the regulatory regime allows cross-border activity, e.g. facilitated by an EU passport, there needs to be effective coordination between home and host supervisor. Since these activities are supervised at national level only, there are no experiences with the supervisory practice for cross-border transactions.
To facilitate cooperation host supervisors could be required to have a complaint office that would receive complaints from debtors about domestic and foreign loan servicers, with an automatic information exchange with foreign servicers' national competent authority. The home supervisor could be obliged to act once it receives a certain number of justified complaints. It could also be envisaged that the host supervisor may get the possibility to withdraw the passport. National competent authorities could make use of the Internal Market Information system (IMI) for their information exchanges. 74
Right to information: Best practices for additional safeguards for borrower rights are early information to the debtor about the loan transfer, information about possible legal defences and complaint methods. As in several MS the NPL purchasers and/or servicers have the same obligations vis-à-vis the debtor as the originating credit institution had it could also be envisaged to oblige purchasers/buyers to explicitly recognise that they assume the same obligation. It would also be important that in cases the transfer of loans from a credit institution to a non-bank reduces borrower rights, legal gaps are addressed.
Possible best practices beyond the scope of this initiative: A number of provisions will not be touched as part of this initiative, although they have been identified as obstacles to the crossborder expansion of loan servicing and obstacles to NPL purchases. Standardisation of the legal instruments to transfer loans, other civil law provisions, debtor protection rights in national law or data protection law are outside the scope this initiative. They appear too heterogeneous to become standardised even if cross-border firms already active on different national markets would benefit from substantial cost savings if these were standardised, and the possible value added of standardisation seems uncertain. Though this limits the benefits this initiative can generate in terms of fostering cross-border market entry, existing firms active in several markets have been able to cope with these differences.
5.3 What is the baseline from which options are assessed?
In the baseline, current rules would continue. This means that specific entry barriers in some Member States would persist and conduct rules that discourage investor entry and the buildup of investor relationship with loan servicers would remain effective. Although there are no restrictions to invest in NPLs in most EU Member States, specific rules on notification to debtors, registration of collateral, localisation and licensing may effectively hold back
74 http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/imi-net/about/index_en.htm
investor entry into markets where they have not been active before. Especially foreign investors may remain reluctant to take exposure in smaller and lesser known markets.
The investor basis for the European NPL market would likely remain at its current size without additional incentives to boost the demand side. While the hedge fund industry recorded growth rates of almost 9% on average during 2015-17 and even double digit growth rates in 2013 and 2014, investment in private as well as in distressed debt has remained rather constant at both global and European level since 2015. Statistical data by Preqin, one of the main data collector on the alternative asset management industry, suggests that the European distressed debt market amounts currently to approximately EUR 20 - 25 billion, including part of the investors that target "special situations" (see Annex 5.1). Investment capacity of this magnitude is consistent with average NPL prices of 20 to 25% of face value and a continuation of loan sales of about EUR 100 billion per annum as observed in the last two years. Profitability in the industry will remain at the currently high rates significantly above 10% observed in the specialised investment fund industry (Annex 5.1) and in firms offering loan servicing (Figure 8 and Table A.3 in Annex 5.2).
If other measures of the NPL action plan effectively expand NPL supply, the baseline scenario means that NPL supply would move along a constant demand curve with banks offering NPLs for sale and competing for a constant investor pool. Without additional demand, banks would not be able to realise higher prices, which increases their incentive to keep NPLs on their balance sheet and evergreen them to the extent possible.
The economic consequences of the above described scenario are manifold. First, the underdeveloped NPL market is expected to mean that NPLs remain on banks' balance sheets, which constitutes an obstacle to mergers and acquisitions among banks, impairing the marketdriven restructuring of the EU banking sector. Second, if banks keep high NPLs on their balance sheet, but do not have the capacity to deal with them in a sustainable way, losses from NPLs can contribute to triggering a bank failure. Third, in a situation where NPL levels would increase in some Member States, they would face limited demand and therewith limited scope to sell NPLs to investors. Finally, in case of stress in the banking sector, banks with low NPLs and a similar asset structure as those with high NPLs risk being penalised by investors in bank debt, leading to higher funding costs for sound banks. Historic episodes have shown that in times of market turmoil investors are not discriminating sufficiently between banks' different asset quality.
Recent trends in NPL volume data show that loan sales in 2015 and 2016 contributed to a decline in the stock of NPLs in the EU by about EUR 200 billion. The exact contribution is impossible to be quantified because, inter alia, some loan sales also covered performing loans and there was no information about the breakdown, and because some loans were sold by AMCs so they did not reduce NPLs on the banks' balance sheet in the year they were sold, but earlier. 75 The EU's NPL ratio fell by 1.4 percentage points over these two years to 5.1% at end
75 For example, one of the largest sales in 2017 related to a portfolio by UK asset manager UKAR and compromised a face value of 11.8 billion GBP in 104000 performing loans that originated from Bradford and Bingley before the banks was taken in public ownership in 2010. See http://www.ukar.co.uk/media-centre/press-releases/2017/31-03-2017?page=4 .
2016. 76 Thus, upon continuation of this trend, which however cannot be taken for granted, it
would take 3 to 4 years to reach a ratio of 2.2% and 1.8% in the EU. For comparison, the NPL
ratio amounted to 1.7% in the US and in Japan in 2016 while the EU NPL ratio in 2008 was
2.2%.
The baseline assumption of a trend continuation means that loan sales will remain absent or
small in a number of Member States and that NPL ratios are likely to remain at double-digit
levels (see Figure 10) in Member States such as CY, EL, PT, BG. The baseline therefore implies risks to financial stability in those Member States where NPL ratios are high and for
the EU banking sector as a whole even if the EU average NPL ratio would have fallen to an
acceptable level after 3 to 4 years.
Figure 10: Development of NPL ratio in Member States Figure 11: Development of NPL ratio in Member States with small or no loan sales with loan sales
Note: Stand-alone banks and foreign controlled subsidiaries and branches. Extrapolation of missing observations by Commission services.
Source: ECB.
5.3 Description of the policy options
This section describes the three policy options that will be assessed in section 6. Table 4 below provides a broad overview of the coverage of these options across the main framing
dimensions described in section 5.1. For each dimension and under each option, the table
states whether the area would be covered by rules at national level, EU level, or both. The main features of each option are the listed under each area.
Table 4: Overview of the regulatory implications of policy options across five dimensions
Option 1 – Non Option 2 –
Baseline binding Minimum Option 3 – Single principles standards rulebook
Purchaser authorisation National National EU EU
-
-Authorisation criteria - Recommend light Broad fit&proper Specific
authorisation criteria fit&proper criteria
Authorisation Authorisation
76 From 6.7 to 5.3% with ECB data, from 6.5 to 5.1% with EBA data.
Option 1 – Non Option 2 –
Baseline binding Minimum Option 3 – Single principles standards rulebook
-
-If use of authorised - - process lighter process lighter servicers
Purchaser business rules National National EU EU
-
-PL and NPL purchases - Recommended to PL purchases PL purchases authorise PL authorised authorised
-
-Loan rescheduling - - No special No special
licensing needs licensing needs
Servicer authorisation National National EU EU
-
-Authorisation criteria - Recommend light Broad fit&proper Specific
authorisation criteria fit&proper criteria
-
-Loss coverage - - Either insurance or Common capital
capital buffers buffers
Servicer business rules National National EU & National EU
-
-Compliance with - MS discretion Enforceable Enforceable legislation conduct rules conduct rules
-
-MS discretion No special No special - Loan rescheduling licensing licensing
-
-National National Common - Supervision supervision rules supervision rules supervision rules
-
-Freedom to Passporting, Passporting, - Cross-border activity establish physical home/host home/host
presence cooperation cooperation
-
Borrower rights, privacy and data EU & National EU & National EU & National EU & National protection
-
-General rights National rules National rules National rules National rules
-
-Right to information - - Minimum Common rules
standards
-
-Privacy and data EU data protection EU data protection EU data protection EU data protection protection rules, national rules, national rules, national rules, national laws laws laws laws
5.3.1 Option 1 - Non-binding common high-level principles
A first option would be to establish non-binding high-level principles that would mostly target entry conditions and conduct rules of NPL investors and loan servicers. These principles cover criteria that investors would need to fulfil to serve as eligible counterparts for banks in NPL transactions and that loan servicers would need to fulfil to provide services to NPL investors. These principles would target areas that are most detrimental to market entrance and that differ strongly across Member States. It would be particularly useful to target a reduction in the regulatory burden in those Member States that have a high NPL ratio and few
NPL sales: EL, PT, HR, CY, possibly also IT 77 , HU and SI.
In order to stimulate participation in NPL and loan servicing markets, the principles would favour a lighter entry authorisation approach for both investors and servicers. EU principles for loan servicers would include a licensing requirement, the freedom to establish a physical
77 Italy recorded a strong acceleration in loan sales in 2016 that continued in 2017.
presence in any EU Member States and the respect for local consumer and data protection rules. The principles would not specifically address the Member States that require a banking license and physical presence of NPL investors, although the recommended approach would be to use lighter entry authorisations. It would further be recommended to lift limitations on the type of loans that non-banks can acquire, i.e. propose equal possibilities for banks to sell performing and non-performing loans or special types of loans, such as secured loans or loans owed by consumers. The principles could also suggest to Member States under which conditions loan servicers can reschedule loan repayments without generating a new loan. In order to reduce administrative delays, these rules would usefully also determine maximum requirements for public authorities to deal with them.
By nature, non-binding common principles would not introduce additional obstacles in those Member States in which market entry is already simple. This could be reached through nonlegislative measures such as guidelines supplemented by country-specific recommendations in the EU semester and/or targeted support by the Commission's Structural Reform Support Service to those Member States most in need. While this option is non-binding on Member States, it would be recommended that Member States that deviate from the common principles adjust their national law accordingly. In cases where Member States establish an asset management company (AMC) that outsources the management of loans to third-part loan servicers and conducts auctions of NPLs, they could implement the principles by incorporating them into the eligibility criteria for loan servicers to provide services to the AMC and for NPL investors to participate in the auctions.
5.3.2 Option 2 - Binding common minimum standards with passporting
A second option would be binding common minimum standards for entry conditions and business rules for investors and loan servicers, including the possibility of operators established according to these standards in one Member State to provide services in other Member States ("passport"). These rules would be oriented along the best practices listed in section 5.2, but would not be defined as a general principle, but include minimum and/or maximum conditions at EU level, that Member States would need to respect when transposing the EU rule into national law. Member States would need to transpose these standards in national law and need to recognise authorisations of NPL investors and loan servicers from other Member States.
These rules would cover more subject matters as under Option 1, and would be more specific. They would establish criteria that investors would need to fulfil to serve as eligible counterparts for banks in NPL transactions and for loan servicers as counterparts to NPL investors. These rules would be based on fit-and-proper criteria (repute, capital requirements or professional insurance, complemented by organisational, IT, risk and compliance requirements) and would determine authorisation procedures and conditions for NPL investors and loan servicers. They would also govern outsourcing possibilities and limitations thereof. Another covered area would be the scope for loan servicers to re-schedule debt and their relationship to loan owners. The standards would require equal treatment of performing and non-performing loans or special types of loans, such as secured loans or loans owed by consumers. NPL investors would be incentivised to use authorised loan servicers. Both NPL investor and loan servicers would be obliged to comply with the civil law of the host country, when acting cross-border and to allow host supervisors to review their conduct. They could also commit Member States to reduce administrative burden of the licensing process and to refrain from enacting some limitations for NPL investors or loan servicers, such as the domiciliation request or the need for a banking license.
They would also commit applicants to not derive additional obligations from the borrowers than they had vis-a-vis the credit-originating bank. The standards would also set limits on what applicants can or cannot do, with enforceable conduct rules that supervisors can monitor and enforce. Since civil law provisions will not be altered, there are limits to additional safeguards that EU standards can introduce. It is, however, envisaged to set up cooperation among supervisors in home and host countries, so that complaints by borrowers about inadequate conduct can be effectively followed up by competent authorities.
Market entry would be stimulated because potential investors and loan servicers could apply for authorisation in one Member State, and would not have to request additional entry authorisation in other Member States.
5.3.3. Option 3 - Binding single rulebook with passporting
A third option would be to harmonise entry and conduct rules in the EU for investors and loan servicers in the EU. This would result in uniform entry conditions in all EU Member States, which would spur market participation and allow the realisation of scale economies. The legal instrument would establish common specific fit-and-proper requirements that Member States require applicants to fulfil and would equally commit Member States to refrain from setting further national licensing and business requirements on NPL investors and loan servicers beyond the common EU rules and the applicable national laws as regards borrower rights.
The legislative instrument would introduce specific licensing and registration requirements for those investors that are not already authorised in the EU, for example as alternative investment fund. Financial firms and investment fund managers already authorised in the EU or other countries would not need special authorisation. Hence, only non-financial firms,
private individuals and firms in specific jurisdictions 78 would need to apply. Eligibility criteria
should be commensurate to the needs, for example covering fit-and-proper criteria and the obligation to respect all the national consumer, debtor and data protection rules. No distinction would be made between performing and non-performing loans or for special types of loans, such as secured loans or loans owed by consumers. In case the acquired NPL portfolio contains also underperforming or performing loans, there would be an obligation to outsource loan management to an authorised loan servicing firm. The rulebook would also include rules that govern the relationship between investors and loan servicers.
The legislative instrument would give a common definition of loan servicing, which could also be positive for market entrance because it would eliminate legal uncertainty. It would establish licensing requirements similar to those existing in some Member States, but with a larger number of loan servicers. These requirements should ensure that loan servicing firms are run by trustworthy managers and have sufficient IT and logistical capacity to offer loan servicing in a sustainable manner. Since NPL portfolios often contain also underperforming or performing loans, some criteria required in Member States for banking licenses should also be considered, for example those linked to bank secrecy. This would also contribute to a levelplaying field between banks' in-house management of loans and that in loan servicing firms.
78 For example if domiciled in tax havens.
Since the former are regulated, it would be inconsistent if the latter were not. The legislative instrument would request some fit-and-proper criteria for loan servicers, possibly supplemented by conduct rules on appropriate behaviour vis-à-vis debtor and data protection.
The binding standards would broadly cover the same issues as option 2. However, under this option the standards on these matters would be fully harmonised and Member States could not introduce more stringent standards to goldplate the common rules. The legislative initiative would also bring additional harmonisation of the supervisory framework. An EU Regulation would be the suitable legal tool to accomplish this.
5.4 Options discarded at an early stage
A less intrusive intervention than changing the regulatory environment would be to set up an information platform that stores rules governing market entry for NPL investors and loan servicers in all Member States. Such a register would be accessible for potential market entrants via a website. Maintaining this website could be done centralised by a European body, such as EBA or ECB/SSM, or decentralised by public authorities in the Member State coordinated via a common entry point or even by AMCs that exist or come into existence in Member States. Member States would need to ensure that the information is factually correct and updated if necessary. The institution maintaining and coordinating the website would have the task of ensuring standardisation of the presentation of national rules.
Such an information platform would be complementary to the data standardisation project in the Council Action Plan. Rather than facilitating potential buyers to assess the values of the loans they envisage to buy in a transaction with banks, it would reduce search and information costs for administrative barriers, thereby helping firms that consider entering NPL and/or loan servicing markets. It would follow the same approach as the single digital gateway (SDG), which aims to improve online availability, quality and findability of information and assistance services on EU rights and national rules concerning the operation and movement in
the EU. 79
The option to establish an information platform is not further pursued because the benefits of reducing search costs for licensing conditions seem marginal compared to other search costs NPL investors and loan servicers have if they enter the market. While the costs of setting up such a structure would also be small, the value added is unclear. Member States that see value in providing such information can do so. For example Portugal is currently venturing this. Moreover, it is not clear whether the advantages of centralisation through an information platform are higher than information provision through competitive private firms. The information platform would crowd out the provision of the same service by consultancy firms.
Table 5: Maintained and discarded options - Standardise and simplify entry and conduct rules for potential NPL buyers and loan servicers
0 Baseline: no policy action at EU level √
1 Non-binding common high-level principles √
79 See https://ec.europa.eu/info/law/better-regulation/initiatives/com-2017-256-0_en .
2 Common standards with passporting √
3 Single rulebook and common market supervision √
4 Establish information platform to register national
rules Discarded
√ := Option maintained and discussed below.
-
6.W HAT ARE THE IMPACTS OF THE POLICY OPTIONS ?
As indicated in the introduction, there is a general need to reduce NPL levels in European banks. The positive economic impact of reducing NPLs from banks' balance sheets will be an increased lending capacity of banks and improved financial stability resulting in increased market confidence, both likely to result in increased economic growth.
The different policy options address a narrow set of actors, consisting of the selling bank, the potential buyer, the loan servicer and the ultimate debtor. The main impact would therefore relate to these stakeholders.
The bank's sale of the loan to a non-bank may potentially affect the borrower and his/her rights. A positive example of a loan transfer beneficial to borrowers would be if the loan purchaser or servicer offered distressed debtors a more suitable payback profile of their loans. By way of negative example, it may also be that the loan purchaser or servicer would treat the borrower more strictly than the credit-originating banks (e.g., due to lesser reputational risks). However, even if the law applicable to the loan purchaser (e.g. the banking prudential framework would be replaced by another framework applicable to the buyer) changed with the sale, the same civil and commercial law, including the safeguards in the consumer protection rules, would continue to apply to the credit agreement based on which the loan is granted.
In view of the above, the transfer of loan from a bank to a non-bank investor does not change contractual obligations of the borrower. However, the change of the creditor means that borrowers are facing a new counterpart with whom they did not conclude contract, who may be less regulated than the originating bank and/or located and regulated in another Member State. Protection of borrowers is the most common reason for existing authorisation procedures in the Member States.
Similarly, information-sharing between investors and loan servicers could conflict with data privacy and business secrecy or, depending on the business model of the loan servicer or investor, lead to risks of excess profiling. This initiative therefore needs to ensure that purchasers and loan servicers comply with data protection rules in the country where the
credit was originated. 80
Although the coverage of the policy options is limited to authorisation of loan purchasers and loan servicers and lightening a few selected behavioural constraints, such action at EU level
80 Issues related to data are expected to improve with the application of the General Data Protection Regulation as from May 2018 and the harmonisation of data protection rules resulting therefrom.
may impact on Member States rules. For example, those Member States that require banking licenses (DE, FR, HU, MT, AT, SK) would no longer be able to do so; those that have different licensing regimes for performing and non-performing loans (BG, FR, PT, RO) would be expected to change the rules. A number of Member States (BE, BG, ES, HU, FI) would need to review the constraints they had put on some investment funds to buy NPLs and BG may need to generalise the permission to transfer consumer loans. Member States that have no specific authorisation regime for NPL investors and/or loan servicers (i.e. CZ, EE, ES HR, LT, SI, FI) would need to designate competent authorities in the transposition of the law.
Other rules in Member States would remain unchanged and would constitute a limit to the conduct of cross-border NPL investors and loan servicers. For example, BE, SI and SK could keep the condition that debtors consent is required, BG and DK their restrictions on debt enforcement 81 . Mandatory notification, notarial certification and registration is required in many Member States and untouched from the coverage of the policy options.
Direct environmental impacts are not expected, while indirect effects would occur only under specific circumstances. For example, a more dynamic NPL secondary market and better possibilities for banks to offload them should create more space for bank lending to environmentally-friendly, or more broadly sustainable projects. Moreover, since these projects are not immune to become non-performing, a better NPL market also allows banks to sell them, which might increase their willingness to fund them in the first place.
81 The proposal to introduce accelerated extra-judicial collateral enforcement will also lead to change in the capacity of creditors to enforce corporate debt.
Figure 12: Assessment of effectiveness and efficiency
Address failure in (national) NPL markets
Facilitate entry in Member States with high NPLs To support banks in specific Member States to
and material obstacles to market entry sell NPLs
Foster entry of smaller firms To support smaller banks to sell smaller
portfolios of NPLs
Foster a single NPL market
Equal treatment across markets in Member States To encourage cross-border expansion of NPL
purchasers and loan servicers
Realise scale economies from cross-border To encourage cross-border expansion of loan
operation servicers and help NPL purchasers realise lower
costs for loan servicing
Enhance competition the entry of foreign firms To foster competition among NPL purchasers
and loan servicers
Safeguards for borrower rights
Ensure efficient supervision To prevent misconduct of NPL purchasers or
loan servicers vis-à-vis borrowers
Costs of adjustment of laws that protect borrower To ensure that borrowers rights are not
rights undermined by a change in authorisation rules
6.1 Option 1 - Non-binding common principles for NPL investors and loan servicers
The option could be implemented relatively quickly if pursued outside legislation at EU level. For example, the implementation could build on guidelines agreed by Member States. Whether such guidelines are able to deliver a quick reduction in the NPL ratio would depend on whether those Member States most concerned are willing and able to amend national legislation along the lines set out in the common principles. This represents the major risk and drawback of this option. At European level, Member States could be incentivised to take action through country-specific recommendations under the European semester, through an accessible list of best practices, or via technical support from the Commission's Structural Reform Support Service. Efforts towards raising political awareness and creating political acceptability for related legislative measures would also be helpful.
Address failure in (national) NPL markets
Common principles would aim to address the most material entry barriers, such as those linked to the requirement to apply for a banking license or to establish a local entity. Consequently, market entrants would benefit from cost savings from less demanding requirements and faster administrative processes. Monetary cost savings might be in the order of a hundred thousand euro if a banking license or structure of a securitisation vehicle is no longer required and there may also be further cost savings if no local entity has to be set up or capital requirements are lower. 82 Still, assuming a reasonable adoption of the initiative by Member States, the monetary cost savings are dwarfed by the large returns in NPL transactions. 83 Though actual cost savings are incremental, it could contribute to foster participation in so far underdeveloped markets. Hence, increased market entry is expected to be concentrated in countries with currently high requirements on the applicant, with long administrative delays and without meaningful loan sales.
Since entry costs are mostly fixed costs and have a sunk cost character, the magnitude of the benefits would be higher for market entrants that are smaller in size and have lower capital positions. Consequently, common principles are likely to constitute a particular incentive for small firms to enter previously ignored markets. One possible business strategy for such firms would be to specialise on bidding for smaller banks' portfolios.
Foster a single NPL market
Since implementation of the common principles would lead to convergence in standards across Member States, treatment of NPL investors and loan servicers would become more equal. In those EU Member States where existing rules already fulfil common principles, potential market entrants would neither face lower costs nor better incentives, but firms based in these Member States would face lower barriers to expand activity to markets with hitherto higher entry barriers. Hence, EU firms that consider expanding their NPL purchasing or loan servicing activity would be immediate beneficiaries of lower entry costs. Similar benefits would emerge for such firms based in third countries.
While helping to reduce entry costs and to let market conditions to converge somewhat, common principles would not create a single secondary NPL market because not all Member States may follow them fully. They could for example maintain or introduce different rules for sales of performing and non-performing loans or have special rules for different types of loans even if the common principles contained a clause that requested equal treatment of all types of bank loans. Moreover, non-binding common principles would not allow introducing a passport and would therefore not allow firms to operate in other Member States without still meeting national authorisation requirements in each Member State, and these authorisation requirements will still diverge to a certain extent. As a stand-alone measure, the reduction of burden in relation to the common principles is unlikely to generate a large incentive for foreign NPL investors and loan servicers to enter new markets. It may nonetheless contribute to more entry at the margin, especially if combined with other policy measures that lead to a greater supply of NPLs, lower information and transaction costs or higher recovery values of the underlying loans.
82 The available compliance data is short, not-representative and shows strong variation across Member States and firms (see Annex 3.2). In order to obtain a better view on compliance costs, DG FISMA will launch an external study to update and expand upon the results of Europe Economics 2009).
83 The literature points to a target profit margin of about 15% (Ciavoliello et al. 2016), actual returns in debt funds investing in distressed debt are about 10% (see Table in Annex 5.1). With an average face value of an NPL transaction of EUR 500 million and assuming a transaction price of 20%, expected revenues would be in the ballpark 10-15 million.
Specific for loan servicers: The reduction of entry costs for loan servicers through common principles should incentivise some loan servicing firms to expand their cross-border activity. The greater ease to establish a loan servicing firm, the availability of more loan servicers and lower costs of loan servicing through more competition among loan servicers would collectively further boost the NPL markets.
Impact on borrowers
If under this option, more NPL are sold from banks to third party entities, more borrowers are likely to face a third-party loan servicer. The latter would be operating under supervision of the debtor's national authorities and in accordance with national rules. Member States will therefore be able to maintain the desired level of borrower rights, even in cases where the authorisation regime becomes lighter as a result of the implementation of the principles (also discussed in the following section).
Safeguards for borrower rights
In those Member States where the implementation of common principles would lead to lighter authorisation regimes, it will be up to national competent authorities to ensure adequate supervision, for example by effective follow-up to borrower complaints.
This option would not have a large impact on supervision and the costs thereof. Member States and those in which a larger number of market participants will be active would receive more applications and need to supervise more market participants. They would need to build up additional administrative capacity.
The main advantage of this option would be that it would leave the highest degree of flexibility to Member States on how to best accommodate them to other applicable laws, in particular those affecting borrower rights. When implementing the common principles, Member States could review whether they entail gaps in borrower rights and adjust either these laws or those laws that implement the EU principles accordingly. This could cause some costs for the public sector.
All in all, the immediate economic effects coming from common principles seem limited. For instance, if the reduction of entry barriers helps kick-start market developments in some Member States, other Member States could follow suit. In addition, once tangible benefits from developing NPL markets are realized, Member States may consider reducing entry barriers further. These indirect implications cannot be quantified.
Table 6: Impact of non-binding common principles (assessment relative to baseline)
NPL loan
investors servicers
Address failure in (national) NPL markets
Facilitate entry in MS with high NPLs and material obstacles to market entry +
Foster entry of smaller firms +
Foster a single NPL market
Equal treatment across markets in Member States +
Realise scale economies from cross-border operation 0 ++
Enhance competition the entry of foreign firms +
Impact on Borrower -
Safeguards for borrower rights
Ensure efficient supervision -
Costs of adjustment of laws that protect borrower rights -
6.2 Option 2 - Binding common minimum standards with passporting
Address failure in (national) NPL markets
The advantage of common standards and passporting would be that investors and loan servicers could establish entities in other countries or provide services across the EU/ EEA without the need for further authorisation if they are already active in one country. The resulting saving of additional compliance costs, legal certainty and avoidance of administrative delays would have a positive impact on the incentive of incumbent market players to expand activity to other Member States. Since the magnitude of cost and time saving would depend on the Member State targeted, market entry would be overproportionally stimulated in Member States with currently high entry barriers. 84 This effect would be larger than under option 1.
A further advantage is a more positive impact on market structures than in option 1. Smaller investment firms or investment funds considering to enter the market or to expand activity cross border would benefit more than larger ones, which are already in the market, because the fixed-cost character of entry costs is relatively more important for smaller amounts invested. Hence, the measure could stimulate competition for smaller NPL portfolios. While the immediate objective of the measure would be to increase competition among investors for NPL portfolios, a uniform passporting/mutual recognition rule would also increase competition on the supply side as investors would face more offers from banks.
84 A quantitative estimate of cost and time is not possible because of lack of data. By means of example, the first loan servicers in Greece were authorised in July 2017, one and a half year after the dedicated law on loan servicers had become effective. First NPL transactions in Greece occurred in 2017.
Foster a single NPL market
Legal differences across Member States could be further reduced, as compared to the previous option, if entry conditions for investors and loan servicers are defined in an EU Directive and the standards do not provide scope for different rules for performing and non-performing rule or specific forms of loans. It is possible that the use of passporting will only be possible if entry conditions converge in Member States. This would also imply they could become stricter in those Member States with currently rather lenient ones. In this case, the common standards with passporting/mutual recognition are expected to still deliver lower entry barriers on EU average than under the baseline. A possible discouragement seems less relevant for loan servicers, because domestic licensing or registration is standard in most Member States.
The availability of a passport could help attract third-country investors because one-stop licensing would allow them to access multiple EU NPL markets from a single subsidiary. In particular, this would incentivise NPL investors to enter markets in which licensing is currently overly cumbersome.
Specific for loan servicers: The possibility to expand activity across borders via passporting seems particularly beneficial for the loan servicing sector, where the scope to realise scale effects is significant. The likely ultimate outcome is lower loan servicing fees charged to NPL investors.
Impact on borrowers
Under this option, NPL sales to third parties would become more common. Borrowers would be likely to face a third-party loan servicer, some of whom would be authorised in another Member State and operating in the debtor's country with a passport. Borrowers would be protected from misconduct of a NPL purchaser or loan servicer through NCAs supervision in the debtor's country, in cooperation with the servicer's home country NCA. Some negative impacts on the borrowers' welfare could result from the fact that the home-host supervisor cooperation could be less effective in dealing with misconduct from loan servicers operating under a passport compared to a situation with national authorisation and supervision. These problems would be most likely in the first years of the cooperation framework, and would be expected to disappear over time.
Safeguards for borrower rights
Supervisors in host countries would need to set up effective procedures to deal with complaints from borrowers and reinforce cooperation with supervisors in home countries, including options to withdraw passports or licenses in case of lack of compliance with rules in host countries.
This option would therefore have an impact on supervision and the costs involved because competent authorities in Member States would need to supervise more cross-border firms. This entails higher complexity of actual supervision, higher responsibility vis-à-vis host countries and coordination needs with authorities in host countries. Competent authorities in Member States with low entry barriers could expect to receive more applications from firms domiciled outside the EU and follow up supervision of these entities, which are likely to be active in other EU Member States too. The regime with passport may therefore lead to higher costs of supervision than in option 1.
The binding common standards could lead to gaps in the legal protection of borrowers if they interact with other laws at national or EU level to the detriment of the borrower. This would be the case, for example, if the authorisation of domestic loan servicers had explicit provisions to conduct rules and the common standards had not or if the national laws impose specific conduct with respect to data protection and the EU rules do not. Implementation of the Directive would give some leeway for the Member State to transpose the rules in a suitable manner, within the limits the Directive allows. For cases beyond this, Member States would need to adjust other laws to maintain the desired status of borrower rights. The likelihood of such adjustment to be necessary is higher than in option 1.
The legislative process for common standards with passport/mutual recognition may be lengthy if Member States consider that maintaining their country specific regime is important. In addition to the time required to engineer agreement at EU level, Member States' implementation would be time-consuming.
Overall, option 2 is more effective than option 1, but at the expense of higher likely hosts to preserve borrower rights and more intrusion in Member States existing legislative framework and sovereignty.
Table 7: Impact of binding common principles with passport (assessment relative to baseline)
NPL loan
investors servicers
Address failure in (national) NPL markets
Facilitate entry in MS with high NPLs and material obstacles to market entry ++
Foster entry of smaller firms +++ ++
Foster a single NPL market
Equal treatment across markets in Member States ++
Realise scale economies from cross-border operation 0 +++
Enhance competition the entry of foreign firms ++
Impact on Borrower --
Safeguards for borrower rights
Ensure efficient supervision --
Costs of adjustment of laws that protect borrower rights --
6.3 Option 3 - Single rulebook and common market supervision
Address failure in (national) NPL markets
In order to become quickly effective, the Regulation would not strive to harmonise the legal tools available to transfer loans. In view of the different legal traditions in Member States, this appears too challenging to be accomplished within a reasonable time span. Moreover, changing the fundamentals of the civil legal system does not look proportionate to the underlying problem and it does not seem achievable politically within a reasonable time span.
Instead, the single rule book would harmonise entry rules, thereby undo specific differences in entry conditions across Member States and particularly the costly obstacles to entry that exist in a few Member States. The single rule book would therefore particularly improve entry conditions in Member States facing high entry barriers by removing entry barriers that result for example from the need to obtain a banking license, to operate via a local entity or to use specific legal vehicles to hold NPLs such as a special purpose vehicle in securitisation arrangements or a specially created investment fund. The removal of some of these obstacles would significantly reduce entry costs and it could make investors more responsive to the NPL supply by banks. In this respect, the single rule book would be more effective than minimum standards.
Participants already active in one Member State would face no additional administrative costs or administrative delays when expanding activity to other Member States. Market entrants could realise monetary cost savings as high as in the case of a Directive and, compared to the baseline, particularly if they use the passport to expand activity to Member States with currently high entry costs and long administrative delays.
This would lead to a significant increase in the NPL investor base if investors expect supply to be sufficient and profit opportunities to be satisfying. As an isolated measure, the lowering of entry costs is expected to have a limited impact on entry decisions given that entry costs are small compared to other costs in the purchase process such as search and information costs to evaluate the value of the NPL portfolio for sale, costs for legal advice and compliance with different legal instruments in the Member States to transfer loans.
The market conditions for loan servicers will depend not only on the introduction of a passport but also on the demand for their services by NPL investors. The latter effect is particularly important in the short run. Over the longer term, the benefits of a more competitive market for loan servicing would become increasingly important. One example is the securitisation of loans, where lower costs of loan servicing contribute to more securitisation activity. Banks would also benefit from lower costs by outsourcing loan servicing to specialised firms. Finally, loan servicers are more IT intensive and smaller in size than banks so they may contribute to the pace of innovation and to technical progress.
The impact on the market structure is uncertain. Larger and more efficient secondary markets for NPLs could foster structural change in the banking sector of those countries with a high
stock of NPLs. 85 As regards the impact on NPL investors and loan servicers, a single market
framework could accelerate market adjustment, possibly encouraging entry of smaller NPL investors. The case is less clear cut for loan servicers. On the one hand, the standardisation of market entry may incentivise smaller firms to enter, accelerating the trend of the last years. On the other hand, the loan servicing market has dynamically evolved in the last years with a number of firms merging or being acquired. Hence, higher competitive pressure may lead to on average loan servicers.
85 For a review of the channels through which NPLs impair merger and acquisitions activity in the banking sector, see the special feature in ECB (2017b).
Foster a single NPL market
The uniformity of rules would establish a level playing field of NPL investors and loan servicers, which is conducive to an intensification of competitive pressure among them. It would also avoid any market segmentation for different types of loans such as performing or non-performing-loans or loans owed from specific counterparts. This should contribute to lower bid prices for NPL portfolios.
Similar to the previous option, the single rule book might lead to tighter rules in Member States with currently lenient ones. For Member States with low NPL levels and consequently a low NPL supply, this measure would be close to neutral. These Member States would become beneficiaries in case NPL problems were to emerge in the future.
Nonetheless, compared to the status quo, harmonised rules would set an incentive for NPL investors to bid for NPLs from banks domiciled in different Member States because crossborder activity will be facilitated. Hence, it will also bring advantages for incumbent market participants. Moreover, the single rulebook helps attract market entry from smaller NPL investors and third-country investors. The former would benefit because the reduction in compliance costs has an over-proportionate effect for them, the latter because they face a larger market. The single rule book may also have a strong signalling effect on foreign investors. Similar effects may also emerge under option 2, but at lower intensity.
Harmonisation of business conditions is expected to have a considerable impact on loan servicers as they would be able to economise on licensing costs when entering several Member States. To the extent that legal uncertainty from different definitions of loan servicing across Member States deterred the expansion to new markets, a common definition would eliminate this obstacle. In addition, the resulting notion of a single market may induce third-country loan servicers to enter EU markets because licensing will be unified and therefore easier. This measure would reduce the costs for an established loan servicer to expand to other EU markets and it would also incentivise third-country loan servicers to enter the EU market.
Since loan servicers' business model is characterised by scale effects, a single market regime is likely to yield lower average costs than option 2. The cursory information about profitability in loan servicing firms active in EU Member States suggests that especially firms are more profitable the more assets they manage (see Figure 8 and Table A2 in Annex 5.2).
Cross-border expansion of EU firms and market entry of third-country firms would also lead to more competition among loan servicers. Both effects are expected to reduce the costs incurred by NPL investors when they delegate debt collection to a third-party loan servicer. The passport would also increase the pool of loan servicers an NPL investor can choose from when bidding for an NPL portfolio. The benefits from new market entries should be particularly visible in Member States having low numbers of incumbent loan servicers, especially if these are owned by competing NPL investors.
Impact on borrowers
Under this option, NPL sales to third parties would become more common. Some borrowers would be likely to face a third-party loan servicer, some of whom would be authorised in another Member State and supervised by a NCA in a different Member State according to a common rule book. Borrowers would be protected from misconduct of a NPL purchaser or loan servicer through NCAs supervision in the debtor's country, in cooperation with the servicer's home country NCA. There could be negative impacts on the borrowers' welfare due to ineffective home-host supervisor cooperation. As a result of more harmonised supervision rules across EU Member States, it should be less severe and disappear faster over time than under Option 2.
Safeguards for borrower rights
As compared to the previous two policy options, there could be a need for further convergence of business practices from a single rule book to be followed by national authorities in the authorisation and supervisory process or indeed a single institution in charge of the authorisation process and supervision.
When a network of competent national authorities is in charge of authorisation and supervision, it will be a challenge to establish harmonised supervisory practices. A single supervisory body may have lower coordination needs, but would rely on expertise on the ground and need to consider the impact of legal rules for the transfer of loans and debt protection provisions that remain national. It is not evident whether supervisory costs would be higher or lower than in the case of a Directive with passporting rights.
To ensure political acceptability of an easier market access for foreign loan servicers, it would be warranted to include in the Regulation obligations for loan servicers to observe local consumer and data protection rules. Alternatively, the Regulation could specify enforceable conduct rules for loan servicers.
In Member States that used to ensure debtor protection through the authorisation and supervision of NPL investors or loan servicers, there could be a need to implement new laws that uphold the desired level of debtor protection through other means. The required adjustment of national law and its implementation will entail one-off costs at national level. These are likely to be higher than in case of a Directive because Member States would have no possibility to consider them in the transposition of the Directive, but would need to channel all adjustment needs into amendments to other laws.
Overall, option 2 is more effective than option 2, but at the expense of higher likely hosts to preserve borrower rights and more intrusion in Member States' existing legislative framework and sovereignty.
Table 8: Impact Single rulebook and common market supervision (assessment relative to baseline)
NPL loan
investors servicers
Address failure in (national) NPL markets
Facilitate entry in MS with high NPLs and material obstacles to market entry +++
Foster entry of smaller firms +++/++
Foster a single NPL market
Equal treatment across markets in Member States +++
Realise scale economies from cross-border operation 0 +++
Enhance competition the entry of foreign firms ++ +++
Impact on Borrower ---
Safeguards for borrower rights
Ensure efficient supervision ---
Costs of adjustment of laws that protect borrower rights ---
-
7.H OW DO THE OPTIONS COMPARE ?
Figure 12 listed criteria against which the effectiveness and efficiency of the different policy options are assessed under each option's assessment in the previous section. The Table 9 below summarises these individual assessments and makes it possible to do an overall comparison of the options.
Overall effectiveness was assessed by aggregating the benefits of the options in addressing failures in NPL markets and in fostering a single market. Overall efficiency was evaluated by comparing these benefits to the aggregate costs in terms of maintaining the same level of borrower rights. See Annex 4.4 for the detailed calculation. Coherence of the options was assessed with regard to broader Commission priorities 86 , but also in the specific context of the related measures of the Council NPL Action Plan (see the section 1 for a discussion of the interdependencies between the various initiatives of the Action Plan). Proportionality was assessed by looking at what measures are necessary in order to achieve the stated objectives, also taking into account the magnitude of the underlying problem.
86 See https://ec.europa.eu/commission/index_en.
Table 9: Summary of options and their effects
Options
Option 1 – Non Option 2 – Binding Option 3 – Single Criteria Baseline binding common common principles rulebook and
principles with passport common market supervision
Effectiveness 0 + ++ +++
Efficiency 0 + ++ ++
Coherence 0 + ++ ++
Proportionality 0 + +++ ++
All the policy options are expected to improve the situation over the baseline, even if their degree of effectiveness can only be estimated. In particular, the lower effectiveness of option 1 against the stronger solutions (options 2 and 3) stems from the Member States coverage. The former would target material changes in a few Member States only while the latter would likely cause changes in most, if not all, Member States. On the flipside, targeting only the most material issues in a few Member States under option 1 would lead to lower need to adjust other legislation to maintain their preferred debtor protection rights, whereas option 3 would require Member States to adapt significantly national legislation. Box 1 below summarises the modelling work undertaken to quantify the magnitude of impacts of the different options in terms of increasing NPL sales. The details and quantification of other effects is provided in Annex 4 and 5, with evidence from the stakeholder consultation presented in Annex 2.
Though options 2 and 3 are more efficient in fostering a single market, i.e. increasing investor base and firms active as loan servicers, than the non-binding option 1, it could take more time before they are effective. Common principles could be implemented particularly quickly in Member States if they accompanied the set-up of an asset management company (AMC) that collected NPLs from banks, outsourced their interim management to third-party loan servicers and conducted auctions to ultimately sell them to non-banks. In this case, principles could be introduced in form of eligibility rules for loan servicers and participants in NPL auctions rather than through legislation.
A relevant trade-off emerges in the choice between options 2 and 3 due to their legislative instrument, in terms of speed of enactment and effectiveness. A Regulation can be considered superior in securing harmonised market conditions and uniform conduct of participants across Member States. Whereas a Directive would allow Member States to reflect country-specific conditions and preferences in their implementation and a Regulation does not, the Directives' additional degree of freedom may also lead to gold plating and reduce effectiveness.
Trade-offs can also emerge between the opening up of competition to foreign entities and the effectiveness of national safeguards for borrower rights. Borrowers' rights do not change with the transfer of loans and, subject to applicable civil law, the borrower can use against the new owner the same defence available against the original creditor. However, the borrower is exposed to higher uncertainty because he/she is facing a new counterpart and starts from a weak bargaining position since he/she has not delivered on contractual obligations beforehand. Since the counterpart is located in a different Member State, the borrower may not know it and not understand how it is regulated. At the same time, opening access to foreign competitors appears essential to stimulate competition on NPL markets.
Options 2 and 3 score better on coherence than option 1, since there is a risk that the common principles will neither achieve a more resilient financial sector, nor will they lead to more homogeneity across the CMU. The scope of options 2 and 3 to accomplish these overarching objectives is comparable.
Option 1 may not be able to solve the issue of high NPL in some Member States and is therefore considered the least proportional, despite yielding some improvement over the baseline. Option 3 is more intrusive on Member States' sovereignty and existing legislative framework, and therefore less proportional than option 2. While Table 11 suggests a clear ranking of the different options in terms of proportionality, this is based on the assumption that reducing NPL is possible and risks for borrowers can be contained by adequate accompanying policies and Member States are prepared to take the costs of these accompanying policies. The ultimate choice will need to depend on the weight given by political preferences to the trade-off between engineering the most efficient or effective option on the one hand and the risk to borrowers and the costs to contain these risks on the other hand.
Overall, the comparison of the effects of the different policy options is inconclusive as regards whether option 2 or 3 is superior. The former has a somewhat lower effectiveness but with a better proportionality, while the reverse is true for the latter. The ultimate choice will depend also on policy preferences. The key question is whether the priority is to opt for a measure that is most effective, or for a measure that maintains more room for national discretion or minimises the scope of policy intervention to the most urgent challenges.
Box 1: Quantifying the impact of the different policy options
In order to compare the impact of the different policy options in a quantitative way, different scenarios were imputed on the pricing model presented in Annex 4.3. The simulation results are depending on a number of simplifying assumptions and could be different if better data was available. The model and main results can be summarised as follows.
A larger investor base and more competition among investors for NPL portfolios should impact investors' return requirements. In the pricing model, the expected return consists of a fixed amount and a country-specific risk premium. For the former 15% is assumed, for the latter is the lending rate to non-financial corporations is taken. The sum of both is a bit higher than realised returns in investment funds (see Annex 5.1) 87 , but broadly consistent with those of investment firms that provide loan servicing (see Annex 5.2). 88 The country-specific risk premium is approximated by the lending rate to the non-financial corporate sector (DK, AT and SE). The benchmark is defined as average profit margin in the three Member States with the lowest lending rates. 89
For the simulation of the impact of common principles, return requirements decline in a group of Member States and for the sample the group was chosen to consist of BG, EL, IT, CY, HU, AT, PL and RO. In these Member States, it is assumed the difference between the country-specific risk
87 The median of the internal rate of return of investment funds in the data panel is 12%.
88 The average profit margin of the firms listed in Annex 5.2 Table A3 is 17%.
89 Lending rates were equally small or smaller in LU and MT, but not considered a good benchmark for this exercise because of the small size of lending markets in these two Member States.
premium and those of the benchmark declines by a third. For the quantification of the effect of passporting, it is assumed that higher competition from a larger and more mobile investor basis leads to a decline of the internal rate of return by 0.5 %pts. This is about the difference between rates of returns of investments in distressed debt in Europe and North America (see Annex 5.1). To reflect that Member States with high country risk may benefit over-proportionally, the scenario also includes that half of the gap between the Member State and the benchmark is closed. In countries with a negative spread, this convergence effect does not materialise.
As regards loan servicers, the common principle scenario assumes a decline in indirect costs of loan servicing by 10% in DE, EL, IT, CY, and AT. For the scenario of passporting, it is assumed that the possibility to realise scale effects reduces indirect costs by 10%. Since Member States with high entry barriers are supposed to benefit over-proportionally from the passporting regime, it is furthermore assumed that half of the gap in indirect gap to the benchmark is closed. The defined benchmark is the median of all Member States, i.e. indirect costs of 9%. This second effect is not applied to Member States with indirect costs lower than the benchmark. For the single rule book, the scenario is similar to those with the passport regime. It is assumed that the possibility to realise scale effects reduces indirect costs by 10% and that half of the gap in indirect costs to the benchmark is closed. This effect applies also to Member States with indirect costs lower than the benchmark, i.e. costs in these Member States would increase. The impact is assumed to be asymmetric, the gap closes by a quarter for those Member States with initial indirect costs below the median and by a half or those above the median.
The Table below shows the simulated impact of the scenarios on NPL sales using the model-based changes in the bid-ask spread (Annex 4.3) and translating the effect of a declining bid-ask spread on NPL sales using the coefficients derived in Annex 4.2 (See Annex 4.3 for more details). The estimation suggests that NPL sales could increase from a level of currently about EUR 100 billion to 103-115 each year. The incremental contribution to the reduction in the NPL ratio will be marginal at EU level. On a few Member States with high NPL ratios, the impact on the NPL ratio would be significant, even as a stand-alone measure.
If combined with the implementation of policy measures, the existence of better functioning secondary markets for NPLs would also help reduce help NPL ratios in future crises. First estimates suggest that a more favourable insolvency framework with a 10% lower recovery time of NPLs leads to a further increase in loan sales by about 10%
Table: Simulation results: NPL sales in billion EUR on the EU and in selected Member States two years after the measure is in place
Scenario A: Scenario B: Scenario C: Baseline Common principles Passport Single rule book NPL investors 100 102.2 109.4 109.4 Loan servicers 100 104.4 121.2 119.8 both combined 100 106.6 130.6 129.1 - memo: NPL ratio 3.1 3.1 3.0 3.0
Impact of combined measure (NPL investors and loan servicers)
on selected Member States after two years
Greece
Loan sales 0 1.03 1.75 1.74
-
-memo: NPL ratio 46.5 46.1 45.8 45.8
Cyprus
Loan sales 0 0.34 0.91 0.91
-
-memo: NPL ratio 42.7 42.1 41.0 41.0
Portugal
Loan sales 2 2 2.8 2.8
-
-memo: NPL ratio 16.8 16.0 14.9 14.9
Italy
Loan sales 54 58.9 71.4 71.4
-
-memo: NPL ratio 9.8 9.6 9.1 9.1
-
8.P REFERRED OPTIONS
The comparison of the effects of the different policy options shows that option 2 and 3 have different strengths in addressing different issues, and do not lead to clear conclusions as to a preferred option in terms of the selection criteria used in the assessment. It will therefore require political considerations to prioritise the choices, based on the impacts and trade-offs presented in the preceding sections.
A single rulebook Regulation that fully harmonises entry and conduct rules for investors and loan servicers would deliver an outcome closest to a single market. Such a single rule book is the most effective measure to increase the investor base for NPLs and reduce the currently high stock of NPLs in the EU and some of its Member States in particular, while ensuring a level playing field among firms from different Member States. It could imply however that certain national specificities cannot be taken into account, and that market entry could become more costly in those Member States in which market entry is already simple, and should be formulated such that it minimises the additional obstacles. Still, some Member States would be required to review whether enactment of a regulation that alters authorisation and conduct rules for NPL purchasers and loan servicers would lead to gaps in terms of borrower rights and data protection and would need to adjust other national laws accordingly.
Since a minimum standards Directive would allow Member States to maintain lighter regimes provided that they respect certain minimum conditions it might stimulate market entry more than a Regulation, depending on implementation in national laws. It could therefore be a good option in increasing the investor base for NPLs and competition on loan servicing markets while allowing Member States to maintain certain national specificities. At the same time it would be less effective in ensuring a level playing field and would give more discretion to Member States to goldplate the requirements, which would prevent these effects to materialise. Some Member States would need to adjust other national law if implementation of a Directive lead to gaps in terms of borrower rights and data protection.
The ultimate choice of the preferred option will depend on policy preferences and whether the priority is to opt for a measure that is most effective, or for a measure that maintains more room for national discretion or minimises the scope of policy intervention to the most urgent challenges.
Independent of the option chosen, the coverage of the initiative would be limited to introduce harmonised conditions for market entry and conduct of non-bank NPL purchasers and loan servicers.
Loan servicers would need to fulfil fit and proper criteria with respect to their
management, prove IT capacity and compliance with debtor and data protection obligations.
A definition of loan servicing would clarify that loan servicers are not originating credit so
that they do not require a banking license.
Their relationship with the NPL investor/purchaser would need to be clarified and
Member States should supervise them given the loan servicers' interaction with the ultimate debtor.
Home and host supervisors would need to cooperate.
Rules for NPL purchasers should be simple, possibly not going beyond registration and
fulfilment of fit-and-proper criteria. Currently, non-bank investors do not face entry barriers in several Member States, while in others banking licences are required. If entry conditions for NPL purchasers would be left outside the scope of EU measures, the
obstacles in other Member States would continue to exist.
There would be no limitation on the type of loan non-banks are allowed to acquire:
performing and non-performing and independent from type of borrower
A possibility to cover NPL purchasers without putting additional administrative burden on
them would be to offer an exemption from authorisation if they delegate the servicing of NPLs to an EU authorised loan servicing firm. If they decide to service loans themselves, they could be treated as loan servicers, possibly restricted to loans with consumers as
borrowers.
Two important aspects would be outside the scope of the initiative:
It would not strive to harmonise debtor protection rules across Member States. A
reassurance of the borrowers' position may be is needed, in light of the many replies to the public consultation that flag debtor protection as a concern of more active secondary markets for NPLs. In any case, for all credits, additional safeguards should avoid that the harmonisation of authorisation conditions undermines borrower rights, including the need to impose the respect of the national rules, reinforced information to the borrowers about
their rights and legal defences and the possibility to file complaints to national authorities.
In view of the different legal traditions in Member States, standardisation of the legal tools
available to transfer loans appears too challenging. Changing the fundamentals of the civil legal system does not seem proportionate to the underlying problem and it does not seem
achievable politically within a reasonable 9. H OW WILL ACTUAL IMPACTS BE MONITORED AND EVALUATED ?
The proposal is expected to follow normal implementation procedures. Ex-post evaluation of all new legislative measures is a top priority for the Commission. The Commission shall establish a programme for monitoring the outputs, results and impacts of this initiative one year after the legal instrument becomes effective. The monitoring programme shall set out the means by which the data and other necessary evidence will be collected.
In terms of indicators and sources that could be used during the evaluation the following monitoring indicators:
NPL volumes and ratios: The relevant data is available from the ECB and from EBA for
all Member States so it is possible to conduct analysis at country level and check, inter alia, whether Member States having hitherto high NPL ratios benefitted overproportionally;
Loan sales in all Member States: this data is not collected officially so data collection and
reporting would rely on Commission services, information from supervisors and consultancy firms;
Composition of the NPLs, in particular amounts of secured and non-secured consumer
credits and home loans;
New purchasers of NPLs, number of smaller banks and banks located in Member States
with hitherto low loan sales: This data would also rely on Commission services’ data gathering, information from supervisors and consultancy firms;
Loan servicers authorised in all Member States and their cross-border activity: This will
be sourced from national competent authorities;
Debtors’ complaints about misbehaviour of loan servicers signalled to national competent
supervisors and supervisors' follow up. Special attention will be paid to complaints about misbehaviour of cross-border loan servicers and their follow-up by home and host
supervisors;
Supervisors' sanctions of non-compliance to NPL purchasers and loan servicers with
respect to borrower rights and data protection.
An evaluation is envisaged 5 years after the implementation of the measure and according to the Commission's better regulation Guidelines. The objective of the evaluation will be to assess, among other things, how effective and efficient it has been in terms of achieving the objectives presented in this impact assessment and to decide whether new measures or amendments are needed. Member States shall provide the Commission with the information necessary for the preparation of that Report.
L IST OF REFERENCES
AFME (2017), Consultation response -Development of Secondary Markets for Non
Performing Loans and Distressed Assets and Protection of Secured Creditors from Borrowers’
Default, October 2017.
Balgova, Maria, Michel Nies and Alexander Plekhanov (2016), The economic impact of
reducing non-performing loans, http://npl.vienna-initiative.com/wpcontent/uploads/sites/2/2017/02/EBRD-The-Economic-Impact-of-Reducing-NPLs-
WP_193.pdf, EBRD Working Paper No. 193, October 2016.
BancaIFIS (2017), Market watch NPL, The Italian Scenario, July 2017.
https://bebeez.it/en/2017/07/19/secured-bad-loans-portfolios-prices-drop-to-33-in-italypushed-by-massive-offer/
.
Barba Navaretti, Giorgio et al (2017), Non-performing loans. Banks, Regulation, and the real
sector. European Economy 1/2017 http://european-economy.eu/ .
Baudino Patrizia and Hyuncheol Yun (2017), Resolution of non-performing loans – policy
options, BIS, Financial Stability Institute, FSI Insights on policy implementation No 3,
October 2017
Bruegel (2017), Analysis of developments in EU capital flows in the global context, Draft
Final report, prepared by Grégory Claeys, Maria Demertzis, Konstantinos Efstathiou, Inês
Gonçalves Raposo, Pia Hüttl, Alexander Lehmann, FISMA/2016/032/B1/ST/OP September
2017.
Ciavoliello, L.G. et al, (2016), "What's the value of NPLs? Bank of Italy Notes on financial stability and supervision No. 3. https://www.bancaditalia.it/pubblicazioni/note-stabilita/2016-
0003/index.html?com.dotmarketing.htmlpage.language=1 .
Deloitte (2017a), CEEC NPL markets in full swing, A record year in 2016,
https://www2.deloitte.com/content/dam/Deloitte/global/Documents/About-Deloitte/centraleurope/ce-non-performing-bank-loans-study-npl.pdf,
January 2017.
Deloitte (2017b), Regulation driving changes in European loan portfolio markets,
Delevreaging Europe H1 2017. https://www2.deloitte.com/uk/en/pages/financialadvisory/articles/deleveraging-europe-market-update.html
.
Djankov, Simeon et al., (2008),"Debt Enforcement Around the World" Journal of Political
Economy Vol 116, No. 6.
Drew Dahl , Andrew P. Meyer , Michelle Clark Neely ( 2016), Scale Matters: Community
Banks and Compliance Costs, https://www.stlouisfed.org/publications/regionaleconomist/july-2016/scale-matters-community-banks-and-compliance-costs
.
Ecofin Council Conclusions on Action plan to tackle non-performing loans in Europe,
http://www.consilium.europa.eu/en/press/press-releases/2017/07/11-conclusions-nonperforming-loans/
Europe Economics (2009), Study on the Cost of Compliance with Selected FSAP Measures,
Final Study for European Commission DG MARKT.
European Banking Authority (2016), EBA Report on the dynamics and drivers of
nonperforming exposures in the EU banking sector, https://www.eba.europa.eu/documents/10180/1360107/EBA+Report+on+NPLs.pdf, July
2016.
European Banking Authority (2017), EBA Risk Assessment Questionnaire as of September
2017. EBA Staff, Risks and Vulnerabilities.
European Banking Federation (2017), EBF comments on the EC consultation on the
development of secondary markets for NPLs and protection of secured creditors, October
2017.
European Central Bank (2016), Financial Stability Report December 2016.
European Central Bank (2017a), Financial Stability Report May 2017.
European Central Bank (2017b), Financial Integration Report April 2017.
European Central Bank and Single Supervisory Mechanism (2017), Stocktake of national
supervisory practices and legal frameworks related to NPLs, June 2017.
European Commission (2017) Reflection Paper on the Deepening of Economic and Monetary
Union, 31 May 2017, https://ec.europa.eu/commission/publications/reflection-paperdeepening-economic-and-monetary-union_en.
European Commission (2017a), A macroeconomic perspective on non-performing loans
(NPLs), Quarterly report on the Euro Area, Volume 16 No 1, pp. 7-21.
European Commission (2017b), Impact Assessment Cross border investment funds,
November 2017.
European Commission (2017c), Post-Programme Surveillance Report, Portugal, Summer
2017, DG ECFIN Institutional Paper No 61, October.
European Systemic Risk Board (2017), Resolving non performing loans in Europe,
https://www.esrb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/reports/20170711_resolving_npl_report.en.pdf, June
2017.
European Systemic Risk Board, Advisory Scientific Committee (2014), Is Europe
Overbanked? https://www.esrb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/asc/Reports_ASC_4_1406.pdf June 2014 Experian (2017), Debt Collection Agencies: The Keys to Improved Recoveries?, Decision
Analytics Briefing Paper. http://www.experian.com/corporate/experian-decisionanalytics.html .
EY (2017), Navigating the Italian credit opportunity, Non-performing loans and new credit
tools, http://www.ey.com/Publication/vwLUAssets/EY-Navigating-the-Italian-creditopportunity/$FILE/EY-Navigating-the-Italian-credit-opportunity.pdf
.
Federal Reserve Board et al., (2016), Report to the Congress on the Effect of Capital Rules on Mortgage Servicing Assets, prepared by Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Office of the Comptroller of the Currency and
National Credit Union Administration, Washinton DC, June 2016.
Fell, John (2017), Microeconomic perspectives for NPL. NPL meeting Venice 15 September
2017 http://www.nplmeeting.it/wp-content/uploads/2016/05/2017-08-24_NPL- Meeting_Venice-15-September_John-Fell_final16_9-format.pdf.
FSC (2017), Report of the FSC Subgroup on Non-Performing Loans, Council of the European
Union, Brussels, 31 May 2017, 9854/17.
International Monetary Fund (2014) Supervisory Roles in Loan Loss Provisioning in
Countries Implementing IFRS, September 2014.
International Monetary Fund (2015a) A Strategy for Resolving Europe’s Problem Loans https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/sdn/2015/sdn1519.pdf and Technical background paper http://www.imf.org/~/media/Websites/IMF/importedpublications/external/pubs/ft/sdn/2015/_sdn1519tbn.ashx, Staff Discussion Note No 1519, September 2015.
International Monetary Fund (2015b), E uro Area Policies, Selected Issues, IMF Country Report No. 15/205.
Jassaud, Nadège and Kenneth Kang (2015), A Strategy for Developing a Market for
Nonperforming Loans in Italy, IMF Working Paper 15/24, February 2015.
KPMG (2016), European Debt Sales, Portfolio Solutions Group,
https://assets.kpmg.com/content/dam/kpmg/xx/pdf/2016/09/european-debt-sales.pdf .
KPMG European Transactions Dashboard,
https://app.powerbi.com/view?r=eyJrIjoiZjkyOTBhOGItZDRiMS00ODcwLTk5YTMtYWQy
NTY1ODNlMmI1IiwidCI6ImRlZmYyNGJiLTIwODktNDQwMC04YzhlLWY3MWU2ODA
zNzhiMiIsImMiOjh9&ed2f26df2d9c416fbddddd2330a778c6=lgkzkosh-lfhhdwzd%20 .
Levitin, A.J. and T. Twoney (2011), Mortgage Servicing, Yale Journal on Regulation, Vol.
28, https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1324023 .
McNulty, J.E., L. García-Feijoo, and A. Viale (2017), The regulation of Mortgage Servicing:
Lessons from the Financial Crisis, Contemporary Economic Policy, Forthcoming.
Mohaddes, Kamiar, Mehdi Raissi and Anke Weber, (2017), Can Italy grow out of its NPL
overhang? A panel threshold analysis, Economics Letters, Vol. 159, pp. 185–189.
Oliver Wyman, 2016, A model for efficient mortgage servicing.
http://www.oliverwyman.com/content/dam/oliverwyman/v2/publications/2016/dec/Oliver%20Wyman%20-
%20A%20Model%20for%20Efficient%20Mortgage%20Servicing.pdf .
PWC (2017), Portfolio Advisory Group Market update Q4 2016,
https://www.pwc.co.uk/deals/assets/portfolio-advisory-group-market-update-2017.pdf ,
March 2017.
S&P Global intelligence (2017), EMEA Servicer evaluation industry report 2016, Global
Credit Portal. http://www.fbs.it/file/news/allegati/news_125.pdf .
Thao Le (2016 ), Information Loss in Mortgage Securitization: Effect on Loan Modification,
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2798849 June 2016.
Vienna Initiative (2012), Working Group on NPLs in Central, Eastern and Southeastern
Europe, https://www.imf.org/external/region/eur/pdf/2012/030112.pdf
Wilson, Nick et al. (2012), Estimating the cost of new public health legislation, Bull World
Health Organ. 2012 Jul 1; Vol. 90(7), pp. 532–539, https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC3397705/ A NNEX 1: P ROCEDURAL INFORMATION
-
1.L EAD DG, De CIDE P LANNING /CWP REFERENCES
Directorate-General for Financial Stability, Financial Services and Capital Markets Union.
The initiative is included in the Commission Work Programme 2018 as agenda planning item PLAN/2017/1121.
-
2.O RGANISATION AND TIMING
Work on the Impact Assessment started in July 2017 with the first meeting of the Steering group held on 2 October 2017, followed by three further meetings on 8 November and 4 December 2017 and 26 January 2018.
The Inter Service Steering Group was formed by representatives of the Directorates General Competition (COMP), European Political Strategy Centre (EPSC), Economic and Financial Affairs (ECFIN), Internal market, Industry, Entrepreneurship and SMEs (GROW), Justice (JUST), Communications Networks Content and Technology (CONNECT), Taxation and Customs Union (TAXUD), the Legal Service (LS) and the Secretariat General (SG).
-
3.C ONSULTATION OF THE RSB
The draft report was sent to the Regulatory Scrutiny Board on 6 December 2017. The Regulatory Scrutiny Board delivered a negative opinion on 12 January 2018. A revised drat was sent to the Regulatory Scrutiny Board on 29 January 2018.
Changes introduced following the first opinion of the Regulatory Scrutiny Board
A new introduction common to all three legislative initiatives on NPL was introduced.
It explains the NPL issue in a wider context and elaborates on the linkages between the various initiatives in the NPL Action Plan in greater detail.
Differences in borrower rights were introduced as problem drivers as well as
discussions how they interact with changes in the authorisation regime for NPL investors and loan servicers. This was also taken up in the discussion on the general
impact of the initiative.
Specific objectives have been aligned with the assessment criteria. The concrete provisions were further specified, including a description of the range
these provisions could take and a discussion of best practices and how they could be
combined to a consistent regulatory regime.
Assessment criteria for the policy options were made less abstract by connecting them
to the desired impact on the main stakeholders.
Possible adjustment needs in Member States are shown in the impact section. The evaluation of the impact of the different policy options was restructured and
expanded.
The presentation of the comparison of the impacts was simplified. The translation of
detailed assessment criteria into rankings is described in a new annex 4.4.
Coherence and proportionality were added as assessment criteria. The set of preferred options was narrowed and the link to concrete provisions this
entails described in more detail.
The evaluation framework was made consistent with that of the other two NPL
legislative initiatives and indicators for monitoring progress were added.
A table with information provided by Member States about their authorisation regime
for NPL purchasers and loan servicers was added as appendix to Annex 6.
Changes introduced following the second opinion of the Regulatory Scrutiny Board
Clarification of the coverage of performing and non-performing loans in the three
options.
Addition of new elements for reviewing the success of this initiative. The additional
indicators cover effectiveness of supervision and compliance with borrower rights and data protection.
-
4.E VIDENCE , SOURCES AND QUALITY
This impact assessment is based primarily on stakeholder consultations, the study of the FSC subgroup on NPLs and background documents prepared for the FSC subgroup, studies by EU and international organisations 90 and additional desk research of the Commission services. More specifically, sources include:
replies by stakeholder to the following consultations:
o A public consultation on the inception impact assessment, 26 June 2017- 22 July 2017. 91
o Public consultation on the development of secondary markets for nonperforming loans and distressed assets and protection of secured creditors from
borrowers’ default, 10 July to 20 October 2017 (closed on 27 October) 92
o A questionnaire to EU Member States 7 April to 1 June (last submission received 4 October 2017)
Feedback from stakeholders and researchers through phone interviews and e-mail
exchanges with stakeholders.
Feedback from stakeholders through bilateral meetings between the Commission
services and stakeholders.
Simulations with the pricing model (see annex 4.3) Cross-country analysis (see annex 4.2) Analysis of annual accounts of individual firms active in the loan servicing market
[and non-public data about compliance costs and their determinants from firms] (see annexes 5.2 and 3.2)
Analysis of the performance of investment funds investing in distressed debt
90 Most notably ECB, ESRB, EBA and IMF.
91 https://ec.europa.eu/info/law/better-regulation/initiatives/ares-2017-3137460_en
92 https://ec.europa.eu/info/consultations/finance-2017-non-performing-loans_en
statistics and data from various sources, including ECB, EBA, World Bank, ORBIS,
Preqin.
Market reports and dedicated studies by consultancy firms (Price Waterhouse
Coopers, Deloitte, KPMG, Earnest and Young etc.);
Analysis carried out for other projects in the European Commission, 93 academic (economic) literature (see List of References);
For a detailed description of the methodological approach, analytical methods, and limitations
of the evidence underpinning this impact assessment, see annex 4.
93 Impact assessment on initiative cross-border distribution of investment funds, 2017; Chapter on NPL in the Bruegel study on monitoring capital flows, 2017, Study on the Cost of Compliance with Selected FSAP Measures by Europe Economis 2009.
A NNEX 2: S TAKEHOLDER CONSULTATION
C ONTEXT
A public consultation was launched on 10 July 2017 with end-date 20 October 2017. It
combined questions on the subject of NPL secondary markets with questions on the
Accelerated Loan Security, which was later re-labelled into Accelerated Collateral Enforcement..
Since the public consultation asked stakeholders to identify obstacles to the development of
secondary markets for NPLs and to give their view on their importance, several responses
gave details on rules in place in the various Member States. Annex 6 focuses on this
information, complementing the information received from a similar questionnaire sent to
Member States.
-
1.C OVERAGE AND REPRESENTATIVENESS OF THE CONSULTATION REPLIES
62 responses were submitted to the public consultation. However, some responses focused on
the second part related to collateral enhancement and did not provide any input to the part on
NPL secondary markets. Among the particularities were that several subsidiaries of one group sent submission, which were similar and consistent, but not identical. These were counted as
one reply. Some associations sent almost identical replies. Since these represented standpoints
of different institutions, each submission was taken individually. Overall, 51 submissions
contained views about the development of the secondary market for NPLs. 10 of them
declared that their submission should not be made public.
The Commission received replies to the consultation from respondents in 16 countries. Most
submissions came from Germany (10) and Italy (8 of which 3 from citizens). There were also
numerous contributions from the UK (7) and Belgium (6), accountable to the domiciliation of
consultancy and law firms in the former and the seats of European organisations in the latter.
4 contributions came from each Austria and Poland. The only submission from a country outside the EU was from China.
Figure A2.1: Number of respondents by Member State
Since the issue at hand has a single market dimension and since third-county investors have
an important role in NPL markets, it is consistent that many submissions came from
international actors. If international associations, cross-border firms and consultancy firms are
counted as representing supranational interests, 29 submissions (57%) fall into this category
and 22 would represent interests in a particular Member State. Although no submission came
from US investors, those of consultancy and law firms may come close to representing views
from third-country investors.
The type of respondents is mixed. 9 replies came from firms active on the demand side of the
NPL market or associations thereof. Also 10 submissions came from banks or their
associations, i.e. representing the supply side view of the NPL market. 8 submissions were
received from other financial associations and 7 from law or consultancy firms. 6 public
authorities replied and 5 citizens. The remaining submissions are attributable to social
partners, consumer organisations and one SME.
Figure A2.2: Replies to the consultation by type of stakeholder
Submissions differed in character and granularity. Some replied directly to the questions,
some added reasoning. The numbers and indications of frequency below relate to those replies
where either a direct response was given or Commission staff was able to derive it directly
from the text. In those cases, where this was not possible, the reply was not counted for the
determination of relative weight of responses. While some responses could not be used to
determine support or not for a specific question, the reasoning and background provided
entered nevertheless into the qualitative assessment done in other parts of this impact
assessment.
Given the small number of responses and their non-representativeness, all numbers can be
taken as a tendency only. If it was possible to trace back differences in responses to
characteristics of the stakeholders, this is indicated below.
-
2.T HE ROLE OF NPL S AND NPL MARKETS
The dominant majority of the replies affirms that the current size, liquidity and structure of
secondary markets for NPL in the EU are an obstacle to the management and resolution of
NPLs in the EU. Some even describe this obstacle as significant. It is, however, notable that
13 submissions (25%) disagree and among them are some firms active in the market or their
associations. Some argue that markets work efficiently at national level, others that the market
will develop.
Question 1: Would you consider the current size, liquidity and structure of secondary markets
for NPL in the EU an obstacle to the management and resolution of NPLs in the EU?
yes, a significant one yes no No reply
Number of responses 11 10 13 17 in % 21.6 19.6 25.5 33.3 in % of those that replied 32.4 29.4 38.2
According to respondents, internal and external factors are relevant for banks to decide
whether loan sales should be a significant part of their strategy to manage NPLs. None of the responses said that external factors alone are relevant. Among the internal factors, the impact
of NPL sales on banks' capital and provisioning, including tax rules on provisioning, and the
role of supervisors are often mentioned, the administrative costs of internal work out is also
frequently listed. A few replies also refer to reputational risks. Examples for external factors were given less frequently and often of general nature, suggesting that the existence of an
efficient secondary market and fair prices would be beneficial for banks.
Only few submissions make a point on whether the lack of investors is an obstacle to market
development and among those that do, a slight majority rejects the notion. More specifically,
most submissions from actors on the demand side of the market do not address the specific issue, while most of those from banks and bank association, representing the supply side
affirm that the lack of investors is an obstacle. Most submissions consider specialisation
advantages and management capacity as the economic benefits of non-bank investors,
followed in frequency by non-bank's general contribution to help offloading their high NPL
level. Occasionally, it was also said that the involvement of non-bank investors could improve
the recovery value of NPLs or that benefits are due to non-bank investors longer time horizon.
-
3.M EASURES TARGETING NPL INVESTORS
As regards obstacles for investors to enter the market, data and information issues are by far
the most frequent reply. Second ranked are non-financial factors, often specified as taxation or
IT issues, closely followed in terms of frequency by legal conditions/insolvency law and
banks' behaviour. Some replies also indicate other financial factors as obstacles and give as example the link of NPL to securitisation markets.
Several stakeholders also list risks and concerns from the involvement of non-bank investors.
These concerns are diverse and cluster around the issues of reputational risks and consumer
protection, a possible information disadvantage over banks including as regards local knowledge, a shift of losses from the regulated banking sector to unregulated entities, the
impact of investors' short time horizons and high return requirements in the non-bank
financial sphere.
The frequency with which main benefits and risks of NPL markets were indicated can be
taken as approximation of their importance. The benefits most frequently listed relate to scale
and liquidity on a deep and large market, and to specialisation gains. As regards risks, consumer/debtor protection and data protection and privacy are very frequently indicated; less
often did respondents see risks from moral hazard. There are also several references to the
equal treatment of investors and the efficiency of the legal framework, which do not fall into a
risk/benefit categorisation.
For a clear majority of those respondents that give a view, differences in national rules pertaining to NPL sales are an obstacle to the development of NPL markets. This view is
shared among firms active on the demand side of the market and other stakeholders. The
opposite view is held by 37% of those respondents that reply to this question. Those that give reasoning argue that either there are no significant obstacles or that the different legislative
frameworks or economic developments justify the differences.
Question 9: Are national differences justified? yes yes with no no with No reply
reasoning reasoning
Number of responses 7 13 11 3 17 in % 13.7 25.5 21.6 5.9 33.3 in % of those that replied 20.6 38.2 32.4 8.8
Question 10: Are national differences an obstacle? yes yes, with no no, with No reply
reasoning reasoning
Number of responses 7 10 5 5 24 in % 13.7 19.6 9.8 9.8 47.1 in % of those that replied 25.9 37.0 18.5 18.5
As regards the nature of obstacles for cross-border activity, the dominant number of responses
refers to the legal framework, insolvency rules and local habits. Much fewer respondents
regard data issues or incentive problems as underlying drivers. When asked whether
differences in these benefits and risks across Member States justify national differences in the framework for the secondary markets for loans, the majority agrees. Among those that
consider national rules an obstacle, 40% finds them justified while 60% do not.
Some stakeholders hold necessary additional rules to safeguard consumer/debtor protection
while others that think current rules are existent and should be maintained. The number of
both views is broadly equal. A non-negligible number advocates specific rules for banks, nonbank investors and debt collection firms. Statements on the need to improve or maintain data
protection level are not frequent, but generally affirmative.
Question 14: Do you consider that an EU regulatory framework (Directive or Regulation) regulating certain aspects of the transfer of loans would be useful? no yes conditional yes No reply Number of responses 11 15 11 14 in % 21.6 29.4 21.6 27.5 in % of those that replied 29.7 40.5 29.7
While a majority supports an EU framework for NPLs, the minority share is sizeable and it is
not possible to attribute a specific characteristic to this minority. For example, while the few
individual firms on the demand side of the market are supportive to an EU framework, three
associations related to demand side of the market are not. Banks and their associations,
representing the supply side of the NPL market are also split. The dissenting minority consists of national actors and those with a supranational perspective. While most dissenting
respondents are located in a Member State with a low NPL ratio, some respondents from
these Member States supported an EU framework. It is also notable that among those that
support an NPL framework at EU level, some make this conditional on a good design that is not overburdening the market players, takes local determinants appropriately into account and
is targeted to obstacles and disincentives.
The consultation replies reveal a broad range of issues an EU framework for NPL sales should
cover. In order of frequency in which issues were mentioned: The link of such a framework to
insolvency law and debtor protection is very frequently flagged. Several responses advocate
measures to standardise the legal process of loan transfers. Some submissions propose measures to facilitate data transfer and data management. The request for licensing of NPL
sellers appears in the replies at comparable frequency. A few replies also make a link to
taxation and banks' capital requirements.
-
4.T HE ECONOMIC FUNCTION OF LOAN SERVICERS
Many respondents recognise advantages from the use of third-party loan servicers and considers them as important for the functioning of NPL markets. The dissenting minority
refers to a lack of evidence and argues that internal work out in banks can be as effective as
the outsourcing to loan servicing firms.
Respondents to the consultation see the role of loan servicers largely in managing NPLs, some
consider they manage both performing and non-performing loans, and very few also attribute a role to them in securitisation and specialisation in real-estate loans. Many describe as
valuable their services linked to monitoring, evaluation and information. Very few make a
similar point with respect to other objectives such as the accomplishment of lower costs of the
management or a higher recovery value of the NPLs.
Question 16: What are the advantages of having access to third-party loan servicers in terms of secondary loan market efficiency? yes ,there are advantages. 20 loan servicers, debt collection important for NPL market/investors 17 advantages from specialisation 19 advantages from scale effects 10 other 8 no advantages 5
Almost all stakeholders that see advantages flag benefits from specialisation. Some submissions argue that benefits derive also from scale effects, local expertise and expertise in
collateral management or help with restructuring debt. A few argue that loan servicers can
help NPL investors in their bargaining process with banks, while a few others argue that the
realisation of advantage is depending on the nature of the outsourcing firm. Points made in
this respect by some respondents are that outsourcing to third-party loan servicers creates new
risks, potential conflicts of interests and impacts the reputation of the outsourcing firm. The impact of outsourcing on debtor and data protection is also regularly listed in this context.
Stakeholders' views are almost equally divided on whether there are obstacles for banks or
non-bank investors to access third-party loan servicers or not. Several responses affirm that
country-differences matter. One respondent remarks that absence of loan servicers would have no impact on NPL transactions taking place. Another one sees advantages from ownership of loan servicers, while a third considers it a disadvantage if loan servicers were
owned by competitors on the NPL market.
As regards the impact on the ultimate debtor of an involvement of third-party loan servicers, a
clear majority considers that it represents a challenge to existing debtor protection rights.
While those that see no risk for debtors or consider existing rules as sufficient are a minority,
some of them make the case that the obligations of the debtor do not change if a loan servicer becomes involved. Others explicitly refer to the reputation of loan servicers as a challenging
factor.
-
5.P OLICY MEASURES TARGETING LOAN SERVICERS
A clear majority considers differences in business practices in loan servicing as significant.
Views are almost equally split on whether the differences are justified or caused by financial regulation. Among those that do not consider them significant are also firms active in the
market and one respondent argues that market entry of international firms has led to a
convergence of industry practices regardless of the local market. As regards activity in several
jurisdictions, relevant differences are seen as caused by legal tradition and consumer
protection rules. Several respondents flag the difficulty and costs to learn and adjust to local conditions and some stress also the relevance of differences in licensing rules in this respect.
A substantial majority of responses indicates that it would be warranted to remove these
obstacles and that this would have a positive impact on NPL markets. The few dissenting
comments argue that consumer legislation requires differences across Member States to be
maintained or that it could have a harmful impact on lending markets.
Question 23: Do you consider that a EU regulatory framework (Directive or Regulation) regulating third-party loan servicers would be useful? no yes no reply Number of responses 7 28 16 in % 13.7 54.9 31.4 in % of those that replied 20 80
A substantial majority supports an EU framework for loan servicers. Only a small minority
either objects or abstains and among them also respondents active in the market or
representing interest of market participants. Almost all respondents that support an EU
framework advocate it should cover a licensing regime and about half of them propose it
regulates the supervision of loan servicers. Several also advocate measures to access data and improve data transparency. Many mention taxation, debtor protection and insolvency law as
framework conditions which, if harmonised, would also improve conditions for international
loan servicing firms. A few responses say that market standards and simplification should be
covered. Single stakeholders also add as warranted coverage of loan servicers' remuneration
structures, qualification requirements for their managers and staff, respect for local rules, debt
collection guidelines and suspension rules.
If yes, what should such legal framework include (multiple replies possible)
supervision of licensing simplification
entities rules and other No reply standardisation
Number of responses 13 27 5 10 21 in % 17.1 35.5 6.6 13.2 27.6
Question 28: What specific aspects could be improved, in order to facilitate existing cross-border activities and/or entry into new markets?
Number of responses in %
Licensing, regulation and supervision of loan servicers 18 58.1
Access to data, transparency 14 45.2
Debtor protection 5 16.1
Insolvency law, bankruptcy procedures 9 29.0
Market standards 5 16.1
Taxation 13 41.9
Measures that target banks 2 6.5
Number of respondents to this question 31 60.8% of total
A NNEX 3: W HO IS AFFECTED AND HOW ?
-
1.P RACTICAL IMPLICATIONS OF THE INITIATIVE
Investment funds and investment firms that intend to purchase NPLs from banks should
face reduced costs in getting authorisation if needed and lower compliance costs when buying
NPL from banks in different EU jurisdictions. This is particularly the case for the smaller funds and investment funds where compliance costs are disproportionately larger. Investors
would also benefit from availability of more loan servicers and lower costs of outsourcing the
management to NPLs to loan servicers caused by higher competition on the loan servicing
market. Higher competition among NPL investors should lead to declining profit margins in
this industry.
Loan servicers, debt collection firms and financial firms considering to enter this business line should face reduced costs in getting authorisation and lower compliance costs
when managing NPLs outsourced from NPL investors to them. Firms acting in different
jurisdictions would benefit particularly from the passport, which eliminates to request
authorisation in each jurisdiction. Tapping markets in different jurisdictions allows them to
realise scale economies. More competition among loan servicers and scale economies should lead to declining fees for loan servicing. Average size and market concentration is expected to
rise while profit margins should decline in the medium term as the result of more contestable
loan servicing markets.
Banks would face a larger investment base and the more intense competition among investors
would lead to higher bid prices for NPLs. This increases their profits respectively reduces the loss they would derive from selling NPL portfolios to non-banks. Banks located in Member
States with hitherto high entry barriers for NPL investors and a small investor base would
benefit over-proportionally. Smaller banks would have proportionally larger benefits because
the larger the investor base, the smaller the size of the average investor and the smaller the
investor the more likely it is that they bid for smaller NPL portfolios held in smaller banks.
Institutional investors such as insurance companies or pension funds are unlikely to be
enticed to enter NPL markets. They are offered a greater range of attractive investment
opportunities in investment funds that buy NPLs as a result of the initiative.
Third country firms would face lower entry costs from licensing if they buy NPLs from EU
banks or provide loan servicing to NPL investors. The passport offers them to conduct business in all EU Member States.
Consultancy firms and law firms may see part of their business and profit opportunities
erode since potential market entrance will require fewer services and legal advice from them
in an environment of less burdensome and more harmonised entry and business conditions.
Debtors should in the first place not be affected because their obligation to pay back their debt and interest is independent from whether the NPL is held by a bank or transferred to a
non-bank. However, they may face welfare losses from uncertainty because facing a
counterpart they had not chosen and do not know, especially if the counterpart is authorised in a different Member State. While they know the conduct of banks from past relationships, they
have less certainty about how the new creditor or loan servicer will behave. Debtors may see a loss in value of their customer relationship with their bank if the bank decides to sell its loan
to a non-bank. This could in turn increase the incentive of the debtor to avoid the loan
becoming non-performing. There is also a possibility that if NPL markets are established,
debtors attribute a smaller value to their customer relationship with their bank. This may have an impact on their selection of banks and conceivably also on their willingness to take a bank
credit.
The potential impact on highly indebted households is hard to foresee as it will depend on
the behaviour of loan servicers. If the latter help indebted social groups more than banks to
arrive at a more suitable payback profile of their loans, debtors may benefit. The opposite is possible if loan servicers apply existing debtor protection rights in a stricter way than banks.
The enhanced environment for banks to offload NPLs from their balance sheets through loan
sales should be positive for SMEs since it will create room for banks to expand lending to
viable companies. Similar the impact on highly indebted households, the impact on highly
indebted SMES will depend on the behaviour of loan servicers. If the latter help them more
than banks to arrive at a more suitable payback profile of their loans, they may benefit. The opposite is possible if loan servicers apply existing debtor protection rights in a stricter way
than banks.
The public sector benefits from lower NPL on banks' balance sheets. This reduces the fiscal
costs of a banking crisis. It also reduced the costs of banking supervision because one critical element of supervision becomes less sizeable. The targeted reduction of compliance costs
could reduce administrative burden for the public sector. Some Member States may face
rising demand for authorisation from third-country firms that intend to make use of the
passport, but may need to be authorised by the supervisor in one Member State for doing so.
Unless the fees charged for authorisation and supervision contain an implicit subsidy for the
applicant, the impact should be budget neutral even in those Member States facing an increase in requests. If Member States see their preferred state of debtor protection eroded through the
EU framework for NPL investors and loan servicers, they would warrant to complement the
policy options at EU level through policy measures at national level in a way that keeps their
preferences in place whilst help develop the NPL secondary market.
-
2.S UMMARY OF COSTS AND BENEFITS
The heterogeneity of the conditions for market entry among Member States, as well as
national supervisory requirements related to the size and legal form of any market participant
considering to buy NPLs, complicate to a great extent the quantification of the benefits of
changes to regulatory standards. Since most investors are hedge funds or private equity
investors, regulatory fees in the asset management industry seem useful to serve as comparison term. If a NPL investor can operate under the regulatory regime of an investment
fund, the regulatory start-up costs would range between about EUR 10,000 to about EUR
15,000. 94 A Commission study suggests that direct regulatory fees could amount to less than
20% and about 40% of the regulatory start up costs might be attributable to compliance costs
in terms of labour costs and to pay external servicers for local facilities in the host country. 95
Annual ongoing costs, for supervision, were estimated at about the same amount. Since
market sources interviewed by the Commission assessed the average of total costs to enter a
new NPL market at about EUR 60,000 to 100,000, compliance costs are deemed not
particularly high in relation with total entry costs incurred by investment firms.
Table A.3.1: Compliance costs of cross-border asset management firms
Note: Scenario A describes an asset management company relying on in-house legal advice and in-house fund administration, whereas Scenario B shows an asset management company outsourcing legal advice and fund administration to third parties.
Source: European Commission 2017.
Loan servicers are subject to costs for licensing in most Member States, with requirements
and compliance costs differing across Member States. The NPL report of the ESRB (2017)
94 European Commission (2017), Impact Assessment: Initiative cross-border distribution of investment funds.
95 European Commission (2017), Impact Assessment: Initiative cross-border distribution of investment funds.
refers to market entry costs ranking up to about EUR 5 to 15 million, but does not specify the
share of licensing costs or country differences. Market sources having replied to European Commission's inquiries indicate that licensing fees vary strongly across Member States and
differences across firms in the same country suggest that both firm- and country specific
factors matter.
From a very limited sample of replies, it became evident that actual one-off fees for the licensing vary from a few hundred euro (in several Member States such as Finland, Ireland,
Sweden) to more than EUR 50,000 (for example in Czech Republic and Italy). Annual
licencing fees range significantly as well, from a few hundred euro per annum to about 34,000
annual fees (for supervision of loan servicers charged in IE). Compliance costs for data
reporting could add to these set-up and licencing fees the costs to comply with anti-money
laundering rules, that may prove significant.
While fees for a banking license may not be particularly high, especially in those Member
States that do not require a full banking license, a banking license carries additional
compliance costs in terms of direct labour costs, necessary to ensure compliance with all rules
applicable to credit institutions, including capital costs to fulfil minimum capital requirements. 96 In the absence of available examples for EU banking sectors, Dahl et al.
(2016) in a US study on compliance costs found that small banks paid USD 100,000 to USD
170,000 for personnel expenses and USD 64,000 - 90,000 for other costs linked to
compliance. 97
According to market sources, some Member States' supervisory framework (for example
Hungary and Romania) require a set-up social capital for loan servicers amounting to EUR 500,000 for NPLs acquisition and debt collection firms, respectively. Greece requires loan
servicers to maintain capital of EUR 100,000. With a standard estimate of 10% costs for
equity, this would translate into up to EUR 10-50,000 additional capital costs per annum if a
banking license is required. Absolute amounts will be different for each individual case, also
depending on the share of capital without a banking license. Similar considerations apply if NPL investors are required to set up a securitisation vehicle or investment fund structure and
this needs to be supported with capital.
Cost structures relating to compliance depend strongly on the applicable legislation and type
of firm. A 2009 study by Europe Economics 98 based its analysis of compliance costs
96 Even in off-shore jurisdictions, setting up a credit institution would imply costs between $150,000 to $250,000, on top of more than $1 million in capital. See https://www.offshorecompany.com/banking/start-a-bank/your-own/
97 Costs for data processing, legal, accounting, and consulting. The numbers relate to community banks with total assets up to USD 250 million. See Dahl, Meyer, Clark Neely (2016) – NAME OF PAPER.
98 Europe Economics, 2009, "Study on the Cost of Compliance with Selected FSAP Measures", available on: http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/finances/docs/actionplan/index/090707_cost_of_compliance_en.pdf
emerging from various EU Directives on extensive interviews with the financial industry. The
results for the asset management industry are shown in the tables below. The one-off costs are not fully comparable to licensing costs since they relate to the investment costs of existing
firms to comply with new regulation and not of new firms to comply with existing legislation.
They may nevertheless be indicative of the types of costs involved.
Table A.3.2 The drivers of one-off compliance costs in the asset management industry by Directive
Note: FCD := Financial Conglomerate Directive, CRD := Capital Requirements Directive, MiFID := Markets in Financial Instruments Directive, 3AMLD := Third Anti-Money Laundering Directive Source: Europe Economics 2009
Table A.3.3 The drivers of ongoing compliance costs in the asset management industry by Directive
Note: FCD := Financial Conglomerate Directive, CRD := Capital Requirements Directive, MiFID := Markets in Financial Instruments Directive, 3AMLD := Third Anti-Money Laundering Directive Source: Europe Economics 2009
Ongoing supervisory fees for banks depend, in the euro area, on the size of the bank and its
risk exposure, by means of a fixed and a variable component. By means of example, a nonsystemic
bank with total assets of EUR 1.6 billion and risk exposure of EUR 700 million
would have to pay a fee to the SSM of about 10,000 in 2017. In the chosen example, about a
tenth of it is due to the fixed component. 99
A recent study by Dahl et al (2016) decomposes the compliance costs of smaller US banks by cost type and size of bank. It demonstrates the importance of personnel expenses as well as
strong scale economies underlying costs for personnel and data processing. Also the share of
costs for accounting and consultancy decline with firm size.
99 https://www.bankingsupervision.europa.eu/organisation/fees/calculator/html/index.en.html
Table A.3.4: Compliance costs in small US banks
Cases of actual licensing costs are only available in form of anecdotal evidence. A market source indicated costs of EUR 60-100,000 to enter a market of which less then EUR 10,000
are caused to obtain a license as NPL investor. Market sources indicated a banking licenses in a Nordic country requires a guarantee depending on the turnover. It would amount to around
EUR 500,000. A German bank founder reported to a newspaper costs of EUR 700,000 to EUR 800,000 to obtain a banking license in Germany. 100 Other online sources suggest that
starting an offshore bank demands between $150,000 to $250,000 and requires $1 million in
capital, depending on the jurisdiction. For founding a bank in the USA, the amounts would be
four times as high. 101
Cost savings would be very different across Member States depending on their licensing
regime, which sometimes entails only a partial banking license. The table below categorises
the examples given in the text below. Given the anecdotal character of some, their countryspecific
nature and different sources, they are not comparable.
Table A.3.5: Overview of administrative costs by type of financial institution
Asset management NPL investors loan banking license
servicers
total costs 19,000-25,000 60- 100,000 50,000-15 USD 150,000-
million 1,000,000
licensing costs 2000 10,000 6,000-80,000 500-800,000
annual fees for 2000 34,000 10,000
supervision
labour costs, costs of 5-15,000
outsourcing
domicilation 5,000
Note: all numbers in EUR unless otherwise indicated.
Box A.3: Cost savings potential from relaxed entry requirements
The actual cost savings by potential market entrants depend on the Member State concerned and more
importantly on firm specific factors.
In Member States where a licence is required for NPL investors, a different set of documents
is often required and the exact requirements upon applicants and bureaucratic procedures vary, resulting in administrative costs and administrative delays (see Annex 6).
Potential cost savings linked to lower fees for licensing and supervision seem to be less
sizeable than labour costs and costs for legal advice and consultancy. In the related branch of
the asset management industry, these administrative costs are at least twice as high as
regulatory fees.
100 https://www.welt.de/finanzen/article138894620/Das-aberwitzige-Abenteuer-eine-Bank-zu-gruenden.html
101 https://www.offshorecompany.com/banking/start-a-bank/your-own/
An important firm-specific factor is the size of the firm. Compliance costs rise underproportionally
with size, partially thanks to scale economies in processing data and to the
fixed cost nature of consultancy costs. 102
Costs savings related to the fact of not requiring a banking license depend on both Member
States' capital requirements and firms' optimal capital position. Member States differ in how
much capital they require from a firm that buys NPLs or acts as loan servicer. 103
Notwithstanding the statutory capital requirement, many NPL investors and loan servicers
voluntarily hold equity as capital. There are also NPL investors that voluntarily hold a banking license since it gives them the advantage of using the EU passport for expanding business to
other EU jurisdictions.
The Table below translates the scarce information about costs that NPL investors and loan
servicers entail if they expand activity into estimates of potential cost savings if any of the
preferred option is implemented. Given the poor data quality, the numbers should only be
seen as indicative. They will be very different in dependence of the individual firm. The
numbers only cover regulatory charges. Labour costs and legal fees would multiply the amount.
-
I.Overview of Benefits (total for all provisions)
Description possible cost saving Comments per firm in EUR
Direct benefits
Lower entry costs for investors for NPL 500,000 if banking All options remove the need to request a banking license purchases in some Member States license was required or set up a local entity for NPL investors
previously
Lower costs for NPL investors to hold 50,000 All options remove the need to set up a securitisation NPLs vehicle or investment fund structure for NPL investors
Lower entry costs for EU loan servicers 500,000 if banking If the EU rule removes the need to request a banking license was required license or set up a local entity.
previously
Lower supervisory fees for EU loan 10,000- 30,000 If the EU rule removes the need to be supervised in each servicers Member State.
Lower costs for EU loan servicers to 6,000 -80,000 per If no further authorisation necessary to enter markets in expand activity to other EU markets market other EU Member States. If the EU rule removes legal
uncertainty from the absence of a uniform definition of
loan servicing
Lower entry costs for third-party loan 75,000 They can select one entry point to the EU market in servicers accordance to their needs.
Larger choice for NPL investors to select #NA The constraint from a limited number of local loan loan servicers and lower costs for loan servicers is lifted. Loan servicers become more efficient
102 See the example of cost structures for compliance of smaller banks in the USA in the Table above. 103 Hungary and Romania request capital amounting to EUR 500,000 for both NPL acquisition and debt collection firms.
servicing through competitive pressure and scale economies.
Indirect benefits
higher bid prices for NPL portfolios #NA results from higher competition on NPL markets
larger transaction volume in NPLs #NA consequence of a larger investor base
Banks lower cost of NPL management #NA from the possibility to outsource to more efficient loan servicers
Banks to increase lending to the economy #NA As a result of fewer NPLs on their balance sheet
lower costs to securitisation with loans as #NA As consequence of lower costs of loan servicing that spill underlying assets over to the costs that securitisation vehicles will have to
pay
lower risk to financial stability #NA from sounder banks with lower NPL ratios and reinforced consolidation in the banking sector
The required re-writing of law and its implementation will entail one-off costs at EU and
national level, especially for Member States that used to ensure debtor protection through the
authorisation and supervision of NPL investors and would need to implement new laws that
uphold the desired level of debtor protection through other means. Costs of writing new
legislation are substantial. Using data from New Zealand, Wilson et al. (2012) estimate costs
of a new law to amount to USD 2.6 million USD and that of a regulation at about USD 400.
They refer to a similar study that point at costs in the US amounting to less than USD 1
million, but find that this study is likely to underestimate costs. As negative outcome, one can
assume that each EU Member State finds it necessary to adjust existing legislation and
encounter costs as high as those found in the study from New Zealand. This would be broadly
EUR 60 million 104 and may represent an upper bound because not all Member States would
need to adjust national law and for those that do, it will concern most of the time adjustment
of existing law rather than completely new law.
Some Member States may face rising demand or authorisation and licensing from NPL
investors and/or loan servicers, which would imply higher administrative costs. Standard
practice is that the public sector charges a fee for the licensing process and supervision that
fully covers these costs. Recent work by the Commission services on the licensing of
investment funds and crowdfunding (see corresponding impact assessments) identified
licensing costs in the range EUR 5,000 to 10,000. One Member State calculates costs of
supervision of a loan servicer at EUR 34,000. Given that supervision of loan servicers might
be more expensive if the entity acts in different Member States, it would be reasonable to
assume that costs increase up to EUR 50,000 p.a.. NPL investors may face lower supervisory
costs if they use an EU supervised loan servicers. These costs could apply to each new
entrant, but would need to be seen in conjunction with cost savings from a single point of
104 2,6 million times 28 Member States adjusted with an USD/EUR exchange rate of 1.2
entry rather than requiring to bear the costs for each Member State the entity wants to be
active in.
II. Overview of costs
Citizens/Consumers/Business NPL investors and loan servicers Public Administrations (per firm)
One-off Recurrent One-off Recurrent One-off Recurrent
none none for license EUR for supervision creation of supervision of 5,000-10,000 EUR 10-50,000 new more NPL
Direct costs legislation investors and EUR 60 loan servicers million
Indirect costs none none legal advice and maintaining It none none labour costs systems and
#/N/A storage of data #N/A
All policy options are expected to lead to compliance costs as regards the implementation of
the new law, the relevant formalities and training for NPL investors and for loan servicers.
Significant compliance costs are expected in particular when it comes to audit and
management, monitoring, supervisory and licensing fees.
While the establishment of principles or rules at EU level would entail compliance costs, NPL
investors and loan servicers would no longer be exposed to the costs of compliance to national
rules. Overall, the EU compliance costs should be lower than the average compliance costs
across EU Member States. Especially NPL investors and loan servicers operating in several
EU Member States should benefit from lower compliance costs.
Given the fact that national rules for loan servicers are generally tighter as compared to
national rules for NPL investors, compliance with common rules is likely to trigger higher
costs for loan servicers as compared to NPL investors. Citizens/consumers are not expected to
bear direct costs. Banks wishing to sell NPLs may be exposed to indirect costs resulting from
the regulatory change if these affect the price bids of NPL investors.
In both groups of market players (i.e. NPL investors and loans servicers), the cost of
complying with the regulatory change is expected to be greater for small players as compared
to bigger players as those costs constitute a greater share in revenues. In the case of small
NPL investors, this initial cost may be compensated over long term with greater revenues
linked to expanded activity across country borders. The described compensation is less likely
for loan servicers, whose operations are characterised by economies of scale. Consequently,
the loan servicing sector is expected to consolidate following the regulatory change, with
potentially negative effects for small businesses but with efficiency gains at an aggregate
level.
Over longer term, i.e. once market participants have adjusted to the regulatory change, cost
savings are expected for the industry on activities such as application for a licence, calculation of regulatory fees, regulatory reporting, marketing. A further beneficial impact on costs is
expected thanks to a lesser need for legal advice due to harmonisation and transparency of rules..
For market participants based outside the EU in particular, NPL investors and for loan
servicers are expected to benefit not only from lower regulatory fees but also the potential
search and legal counsel costs, facilitating access to EU markets.
From consumer perspective, the obligation to respect national rules for privacy, data and debtor protection for loan servicers is key to ensure an adequate and predictable level of
consumer protection in all EU countries.
A NNEX 4: A NALYTICAL METHODS
-
1.A STYLISED VIEW ON DEMAND AND SUPPLY OF THE NPL MARKET
The first part of this annex presents a conceptual framework to analyse the potential impact of policy measures on the demand for and supply of non-performing loans on secondary markets. To put the initiative analysed in this text into perspective, the appendix gives a schematic overview of the different NPL initiatives and of the specific failures they address, such as shortage of supply, lack of demand, information costs, valuation.
The presented framework is theoretical as data availability does not allow a derivation of full quantitative properties of demand, supply and of the market equilibrium. A further
complication arises from the fact that non-performing loans are not a homogenous good,
which is evidenced by different prices for secured (largely by real estate) and non-secured
(largely consumer loans). 105 Finally, the structure of the NPL market is that of an oligopsony, with few large buyers conducting a small number of transactions. 106 Notwithstanding the
mentioned difficulties, it seems possible to derive stylised characteristics of the NPL demand
and supply function based on the incentives that investors (the demand side) and banks (the
supply side) face.
The proposed framework considers a simplified model of the NPL market with a portfolio
consisting of a large number of homogenous loans. Looking at the supply side, the higher the market price relative to the nominal value (the gross book value), the higher the volume of
NPLs proposed for sale. One can also assume a price floor below which banks will not offer
any NPLs. Determinants of this floor could be: i) a (non-negative) expected recovery value on
the loan portfolio, and ii) the desire by a bank not to realise capital losses, which may arise if
the market price is too much below the expected recovery value. Even if the debtor does not pay back his loan, the bank may anticipate that he pays back part of the loan and may
therefore wish to keep the loan on its books. Banks may also refuse to sell NPLs if they
esteem the customer relationship and hope for ongoing business with the debtor, which could
become profitable again. 107 The mentioned mechanism may result in a price ceiling.
Moreover, the offer price may reflect potential reputational costs for a bank linked to NPL sales and their negative impact on long-term relationships with its clients. Finally, strategic
considerations may also determine the offer price. For example, the bank may anticipate that
the bidder will try to exploit its weak bargaining position if it has a large pile of NPLs on its
105 Prices for secured (largely by real estate) and non-secured (largely consumer loans) are very different. Italian buyer BancaIFIS (2017) shows divergent price trends for secured and unsecured NPL transactions in Italy.
106 See Fell (2017).
107 Banks will have to decide when to keep the NPL on their books depending on the difference between the market price and the book value of a non-performing loan
balance sheet. Therefore, the bank may strategically decide to enter negotiations with a
somewhat inflated offer price.
In the chart below we assume that at a market price equalling the nominal value banks will
offer 70% of NPLs for sale (i.e. keep 30% of the NPLs on their loan book). We also assume
that banks will not supply any NPLs to the market at a market price equal or lower less than
20% of the nominal value.
Figure A.4.1: A stylised perspective on demand for and supply of NPLs
Looking at the demand side, potential investors are expected not to offer a price much below
the highest recovery value of the NPLs offered because it would be refused by banks.
Although investors' expectations on recovery values may differ from related expectations by
banks, the discrepancy may not be too significant. At the same time, investors are likely to
demand a price that covers their costs of administering the NPLs, which may justify the
discount as compared to the recovery value. NPL investors are also likely to request an addon
that reflects funding costs and/or their internal requested rate of return. Both seem to be
higher for non-banks than for banks.
For a zero market price, demand for NPLs is expected to amount to the entire loan book as
investors are willing to take the total loan book if it is for free. As to the shape of the demand
curve, the relationship between price and demanded volumes is expected to be non-linear for
strategic reasons. For smaller shares of NPLs offered, the investor may anticipate a lemon
issue: the counterpart could offer NPLs with the weakest recovery value and keep the higher
quality NPLs on the balance sheet. The described mechanism could in the extreme case lead
to a demand curve which is backward bending in parts, i.e. demand declines when prices
decline. 108 While it is not possible to identify the range in which the demand curve is
backward bending, one can at least assume that the demand curve is steeper (i.e. more elastic to changes in prices) for lower volumes of NPLs. The larger the share of NPLs sold, the less
relevant the lemon issue. For larger shares of NPLs offered, non-linearity may occur due to
efficiency gains in loan administration, for example by realising scale effects in loan servicing
and debt collection.
NPL transactions are done with consultants, which charge a price for their services. The
added value of the consultancy services is to match demand and supply, which is not trivial
given the opacity of the market, the underlying lemon issue and the bilateral bargaining
position of both the buyer and the seller, requiring a tailor-made contract that encompasses all
information and incentive asymmetries. These transaction costs are reflected in a bid-ask spread, which can be charged either on the selling banks or on the buying investors. The chart
above assumes that the transaction costs increase the costs for investors proportional to the
price and move the demand curve northwards.
Both the demand and the supply curve may be affected by policy options listed in the NPL
action plan. More efficient insolvency frameworks would increase the recovery value of
NPLs, thereby shifting both demand and supply upwards. Market prices would increase, but the effect on volumes is uncertain, depending on whether banks or non-bank debt collectors
could benefit more from the improved insolvency framework. Another element potentially
leading to a changed market outcome is supervisory pressure on banks to disclose NPLs
and/or to off-load them from their balance sheet. If banks face stronger incentives to provision
NPLs, the book value declines relative to the nominal value, which reduces the gap to the market price. The mentioned supervisory pressure has the potential to shift the supply curve
downwards, thereby decreasing prices and increasing volumes. An establishment of AMCs
could have a similar effect as it would incentivise banks to supply more NPLs if transactions
are arranged by a third-party with possibly larger bargaining power and smaller stigma
effects. The direct consequence could also be lower transaction costs if the AMC economises on some of the activity that consultants are undertaking.
On the investor side, the existence of an AMC on the market would likely lower search costs
but it could strengthen the bargaining position of their counterpart (i.e. the bank selling
NPLs). AMCs and information platforms could also reduce transaction costs by providing
impartial information to potential buyers, i.e. facilitating due diligence and reducing information asymmetries between the initial creditor and potential buyer of the debt contract.
If the transaction costs are ultimately paid by the investor, the involvement of AMCs and
information platforms will move the demand curve upwards, i.e. closer to the curve without
transaction costs. More efficient securitisation markets would be largely to the benefit of
108 This is depicted in a chart in the ECB Financial Stability report December 2016, p. 129. See also Fell (2017).
lower funding costs for NPL transactions, which could move the demand curve upwards as
investors could afford to pay a higher price for NPLs.
Lowering market entry conditions for investors into the secondary market for NPLs would
shift the demand curve to the right, but the impact on the reservation price is unclear as it is
uncertain whether new entrants would be able to realise higher recovery values. Both
recurrent and one-off costs may constitute market entry barriers as they affect the result of a cost-benefit analysis undertaken by a potential entrant. As to one-off costs, they cannot be
recovered if the firm is not able to do successful business (so-called sunk costs) and they
include: obtaining authorisation and licenses, investments to become eligible for national
conditions, search for loan servicer. Examples of recurrent costs include: debt collection,
collateral use, compliance to conduct rules.
Figure A. 4.2: An economic perspective on different policies to tackle NPLs in EU banks
-
2.C ROSS COUNTRY ANALYSIS
This part derives insights from the cross-country variation in selected NPL data. The
comparison covers the EU Member States. For some exercises, data was not avaialable
for all EU Member States and in some comparisons it turns out that the UK observations
were outliers. In some of the latter cases, the observations for the UK were not considered. Overall, the quality of the data basis is weak. Despite the weak data quality,
most of the found correlation look plausible and evidence of a systematic bias in the data
that would distort the results could not be detected. This said, the resulting numbers
should be best understood as illustrative only as they do not stand up to the requirements
of rigorous robustness checks.
The only official statistics available for NPLs are volumes of NPLs on banks' balance sheets and their ratio to loans and advances on banks' balance sheets collected by EBA
and ECB. Since the coverage of banks is larger in the ECB than in the EBA data file,
ECB data was used for the analysis.
The only source for data on NPL sales are international consultancy firms and they
collect the data from public sources, own business and business contacts. Data collected and made public by the different consultancy firms is broadly similar, but differs
somewhat, which indicates that the underlying ground work is difficult and there are
limited means to verify data. Issues emerging from data quality are discussed below. For
the analysis in this section, the data of NPL sale by Member State 2015 and 2016
published in PWC (2017) and Deloitte (2017). For ratios, the loan sales data of the year was combined with the stock of NPLs in the same Member State's banks' balance sheet at
the end of the previous year, i.e. 2016 transactions relative to the stock in 2015Q4.
Even if consultancy firms strive to have a high standard on data collection, they do not
have the means and authority to verify data to the same extent public statistical offices
can. Hence, there may be a bias in the data emerging from the possibility that some loan sales take place without any notification to the public. Another issue is that the available
data is patchy, i.e. not all data fields are complete. For example, the amount traded is not
disclosed or available in more than 15% of the transactions, in one micro data set the
Commission services were able to check. The consequence is that observations for
Member States with few transactions and a large share of transactions with unknown
amount cannot be used. This led to the decision not to consider the observations for Belgium in the analysis below.
Another complication for any empirical analysis with this data stems from the
observations that underlying transactions are very different in size and a few very large
transactions will determine observations for some Member States. This may cause
outliers to have a strong impact on descriptive and analytical statistics. Since the largest transactions are clustered in Member States with a larger number of transactions (UK, IT,
ES, DE, IE), the risk of empirical results being determined by individual loan sales
appears limited.
In almost 25% of the transactions, buyer respectively seller are not known. Hence it cannot be said whether the NPLs were sold or bought by non-banks or other banks. Very
often loan sales combine the sale of non-performing with performing loans. Given the
uncertain sourcing of the data, it may even be possible that some transactions are carried
out with performing loans only. An example that combines several of these two issues is
the sale of a portfolio with a face value of 11.8 billion GBP by UKAR to Prudential and Blackstone in May 2017. 109 The amount is equal to about 10% of the total annual
turnover in 2016. The seller is not a bank, but a public AMC. The underlying 104,000
loans are performing and they had been originated by the bank Bradford and Bingley
before it was put in public ownership in 2008.
While the share of NPLs in the reported loan sales is unknown, three different methods suggest it could be on average in the range of 70 to 80%.
A first estimate stems from AFME and is reported in its reply to the public
consultation. According to data from KPMG "74% of the total loans sales
completed between 2015 and 1H 2017 in Europe represented either nonperforming
or a mixture of non-performing loans with other risk exposures (i.e.
with performing, subprime, or re-performing loans)."
A second estimate was conducted by the Commission Services with data from
another consultancy firm shows a share of non-performing loans in loan transactions of 47% on average 2014-2016. It also reveals that for 34% of the
loan amounts there is no information whether they are performing or nonperforming
and in 12% the loan amount was a mixed portfolio, consisting of a
unknown share of performing and no- performing loans. If it is assumed that the
ratio is the same in the unknown and mixed transactions as in the trades with a
known breakdown, the ratio of non-performing loans in all loan trades would be 78%.
A third method consists in a regression analysis that relates the loan sales in 15
EU Member States to the change in the volume of non-performing loans on
banks' balance sheets (see chart below). The regression line suggests that for 100
billion EUR loan sales, the amount of non-performing loans declines on averge
by 73 billion, i.e. an implied proportion of 73% of non-performing loans in total loan sales. If the outlying observation of the UK is not considered, the ratio would
increase to 80%.
109 See UKAR's press release of the deal at http://www.ukar.co.uk/media-centre/press-releases/2017/31-03-
Figure A 4.3 Loan sales and change in NPL volumes across EU Member States
10
ks in PL
4 00 FR HR BG LT
n ban 6Q SI PT
o HU RO PL 2 01 -10 NL f N 4 to
e o U
R -20
m 4Q DE
lu 01
n E IT -30
e vo ts
2 billio
th ee -40
y = -0.7334x - 1.9487 IE R² = 0.8619
in ES e sh
ge -50 UK
an la
nc
Ch ba -60
0 20 40 60 80
Loan sales 2015/16 in billion EUR
The chart below applies the same methodology, but does not take loan sale and NPL
volumes in EUR, but as a ratio to the stock of NPLs and total loans, respectively. This is
an implicit control for the size of the market and avoids that Member States with large
NPLs have a dominant impact on the correlation. The correlation is insignificant and the
R2 small unless the UK as outlier is excluded from the panel. If the UK observation is
not considered, the regression line suggests that a 1 %-pt increase in the ratio of loan
sales to NPL volumes decreases the NPL ratio by 0.3%-pts.
Figure A 4.4 Loan sales and change in NPL ratios across EU Member States
.
The next chart applies the same methodology, but uses a different data set, namely loan
sales submitted and calculated by AFME on the basis of data collected from KPMG from
public data sources. This data set includes an observation for SE, but misses some EU
Member States (FR, LT). Numbers are broadly comparable with the exception of those for UK and HR. Still, the slope coefficient is similar and the share explained by the
regression line somewhat higher, even if the UK is not excluded from the panel.
Figure A 4.5 Loan sales and change in NPL ratios across EU Member States (alternative data source)
A further cross-country comparison shows some correlation between loan sales and the
bid-ask spread derived from the theoretical model presented in Annex 4.3. While the R2
is not particularly high, the correlation is significant at 5% level independent of whether
the UK is included into the sample or not. Though the regression analysis gives no
information about causality, it suggests a 10%-pts decline in the bid-ask spread would be
consistent with an 3.3 to 4.5 %pt increase in loan sales relative to the outstanding NPL
stock. If the initial NPL ratio or the market size are added as additional control variable,
they does not come out significant, and do not change the significance of the bid-ask
spread.
Figure A 4.6 Loan sales and bid ask spread across EU Member States
Since for some Member States there is not data about loan sales, it is also interesting to
directly compare the bid-ask spread derived from the model with the change in NPL ratios. For both data is available for all Member States, bar CZ for which the NPL ratio in
the ECB data set starts only with the observation of 2016Q1. The relationship between
bid-ask spread and the change in the NPL ratio from 2014Q4 to 2016Q4 is not
significant. This, however, changes, if the observations for those Member States, in
which the NPL ratio increased over these two years are excluded from the panel (BG, EL and PT). Since the reasons for an increase in the NPL ratio are unrelated to the bid-ask
spread that impacts the loan sales, such elimination of single observations from the data
set seems justified. The correlation become significant and suggests Member States with
a lower bid-ask spread were able to realise a relatively larger decline in their banks' NPL
ratio. The slope coefficient suggests a 1 %pt lower bid-ask spread reduces the NPL ratio
by 1.6%.
Figure A.4.7 Change in NPL ratio and bid ask spread across EU Member States
The table below shows the numerical results of the different specifications.
Table A4.1 Regression results, cross-country OLS, dependent variables Loan sales (upper panel) and change in NPL ratio (bottom panel)
Bid-ask Constant spread R2 obs.
Transactions in loan sales
Data set 1 23.94 -0.72 0.24 16
t-value 3.65 -2.08
Data set 1 ex UK 21.60 -0.66 0.30 15
t-value 4.04 -2.34
Data set 2 21.43 -0.70 0.27 14
t-value 3.44 -2.09
% Change in NPL ratio -
Data set 3 38.35 0.89 0.05 27
t-value -2.81 1.20 -
Data set 3 ex BG, EL and PT 57.04 1.65 0.39 24
t-value -7.10 3.79 Note: Bid ask spreads as derived in Annex 4.3. Data set 1 combines observations of loan sales 2015 and 2016 in
PWC (2017) and Deloitte (2017). Data set 2 uses the AFME (2017) calculations with KPMG data of loan sales. All loan sale data is relative to the ECB data of NPL volumes. Data set 3 uses the change in the ECB's NPL ratio 2014Q4 to 2016Q4 (2015Q1 for those Member States that had no observation for 2014Q4).
There is also a broad correlation between the number of loan servicers active in a Member State and the volume of NPLs. The number of loan servicers is taken from Table A2 in Annex 5.2. The right-hand panel zooms in on smaller Member States, that
are not clearly visible in the left-hand panel. The comparison suggests that the number of
loan servicers relative to the amount of non-performing loans is small in Italy, France,
and despite numerous authorisations recently in Greece. 110 Spain and Portugal are
borderline cases. The UK is also an outlier since it has many loan servicers. This might
be explainable by the role loan servicers have in supporting securitisation activity or the
outsourcing of the management of real estate loans in the UK.
Figure A.4.8 Number of loan servicers and NPL volume across EU Member States
Although the cross-country comparisons produce plausible coefficients, the small
number of observations and the data caveats listed above suggest that the result are best
treated as illustration and not at statistical evidence. Results may not be robust and change once the analysis is re-run with observations for more countries or additional
years.
110 The first loan servicer was authorised in Greece in July 2017. By December 2017, the Greek
Central Bank authorised 10 firms.
-
3.Q UANTIFYING THE IMPACT OF THE DIFFERENT POLICY OPTIONS ON NPL SECONDARY MARKETS - EXPLANATION AND ASSUMPTIONS
Inefficiencies in the pricing of NPLs show up as relatively wide spreads between the ask
price from the sellers of NPLs and the bid price from buyers. Then, one of the goals of
the difference policy options is to improve NPLs secondary market efficiency helping to reduce such spread. We observed that a reduction in the bid-ask spread is correlated with
a reduction in the NPL ratio.
Pricing model for the bid-ask spread
We have implemented a theoretical model to calculate the bid ask spread on NPLs for the
EU MS:
We apply the methodology proposed by Ciavoliello, et al (2016) and proceeded as
follows:
-
1.The future value of a loan that performs and that matures at time n is Fn. This loan has
cash flows (f t ) from now until maturity in time n. We use the loan effective rate (i) to
calculate the future value.
𝑛
𝐹 𝑡 𝑛 = ∑ 𝑓 𝑓 ∗ (1 + 𝑖) = 100
𝑡=1
-
2.To calculate the present value of a performing loan (Gross Book Value or GBV u ) we
discount the future value of the loan (Fn) using the loan effective interest rate (i). Thus:
𝐺𝐵𝑉 𝑢 = 𝐹 𝑛 (1 + 𝑖) 𝑛
-
3.If the loan defaults or does not perform (NPL), the owner (bank) of the loan can only
recover a percentage on the GBV u (recovery rate = rr). Then the Gross Book Value of the defaulted loan (GBV d ) is:
𝐺𝐵𝑉
𝑑 = 𝐺𝐵𝑉 𝑢 ∗ 𝑟𝑟
-
4.If the loan becomes non-performing it incurs in some costs to either default management or loss mitigation that we name indirect costs (ic). These costs are the fee
that the loan servicer will charge for their services and it is a percentage of the Gross
Value of the default loan. Then, the net value of the default loan (NBV d ) is:
𝑁𝐵𝑉
𝑑 = 𝐺𝐵𝑉 𝑑 (1 − 𝑖𝑐)
-
5.Then, the bank with NPL has to provision for the losses in the loan. The provisions
should be the difference between the GBV u and the GBV d :
𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑣𝑖𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛 = 𝐺𝐵𝑉
𝑢 − 𝐺𝐵𝑉 𝑑
-
6.To avoid further losses on the loan, the bank will be willing to sell the NPL at GBV d .
Any price above this value will generate profits and any price below will further damage
the bank profitability and its capital position. Then, our ask price estimation for the loan,
the minimum price at which the bank would be willing to sell the loan, is GVB d :
𝑎𝑠𝑘 = 𝐺𝑉𝐵 𝑑
-
7.The ask price will be higher if the NPL is under provision to avoid inputting further
losses in the income statement. The more in need of capital and under provisioned the
higher the ask price by the seller bank.
𝑖𝑓 𝑝𝑟𝑜𝑣𝑖𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛 < 𝐺𝐵𝑉
𝑢 − 𝐺𝐵𝑉 𝑑
𝑎𝑠𝑘 = 𝐺𝑉𝐵
𝑢 − 𝑝𝑟𝑜𝑣𝑖𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛
-
8.Potential NPL buyers need to take into consideration the GBV d , the indirect costs to
recover the loan (ic) and its expected profit. This expected profit should be weighted by risk. However, for simplicity reasons, our assumption is a plain profit of 15% on top of
the loan effective interest rate. Then, the bid price, the maximum price that the buyer is
willing to pay will be:
𝑏𝑖𝑑 = 𝐹 𝑛 ∗ 𝑟𝑟 (1 + 𝑖 + 0.15) 𝑛 − 𝑖𝑐
-
9.The bid ask spread in the secondary market for NPLs will be:
𝑏𝑖𝑑 𝑎𝑠𝑘 𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 = 𝑎𝑠𝑘 − 𝑏𝑖𝑑
Then the drivers of the differences in bid ask spread among EU MS will be:
-
a.The loan effective rate
-
b.The time to recover the loan
-
c.The recovery rate d. The indirect costs
-
e.The provisions
-
f.The buyer expected profit
Calibration of the model
To provide an estimation of the differences in bid ask spread on NPLs among MS, we
have gathered information from World Bank, Doing Business 2016.
The loan effective rate is calculated for every MS using the interest rate of new lending
to non-financial corporations with a maturity of 1-5 years. This data is compiled by the
ECB.
We use the time to recover the loan, the recovery rate and the indirect costs provided by The World Bank in its publication Doing Business 2016. The values of these variables
for each MS are calculated based on the time, cost and outcome of insolvency
proceedings in a given economy.
Time remaining to collect the cash flow from the NPL loan is provided either by NBER
and Doing Business. NBER data is from 2006 whereas data from World Bank is from 2016. The values are not the same but the differences are small for all the Member States
but the Czech Republic and Romania.
To make the data on recovery rate comparable across countries, several assumptions
about the business and the case are used. The recovery rate is recorded as cents on the
dollar recovered by secured creditors through reorganization, liquidation or debt enforcement (foreclosure or receivership) proceedings. The calculation takes into account
the outcome: whether the business emerges from the proceedings as a going concern or
the assets are sold piecemeal. Then the costs of the proceedings are deducted (1 cent for
each percentage point of the value of the debtor’s estate). Finally, the value lost as a
result of the time the money remains tied up in insolvency proceedings is taken into
account, including the loss of value due to depreciation of the hotel furniture. Consistent with international accounting practice, the annual depreciation rate for furniture is taken
to be 20%. The furniture is assumed to account for a quarter of the total value of assets.
The recovery rate is the present value of the remaining proceeds, based on end-2015
lending rates from the International Monetary Fund’s International Financial Statistics, supplemented with data from central banks and the Economist Intelligence Unit. It is
important to note that the drivers of the recovery rate, i.e. the cost, the time and the
binary outcome of the process (the company continues to operate or is sold piecemeal)
are derived from questionnaire responses by local insolvency practitioners and verified
by the World Bank through a study of laws and regulations as well as public information
on insolvency systems. In other words, the recovery rates calculated by the World Bank are not directly based on an average of observed recovery rates.
The estimated cost of the insolvency proceeding or indirect costs are reported as a
percentage of the value of the insolvency estate, borne by all parties. Costs include
court/bankruptcy authority costs, attorney fees, bankruptcy administrator fees, accountant
fees, notification and publication fees, assessor or inspector fees, asset storage and preservation costs, auctioneer fees, government levies and other associated insolvency
costs. These costs will be mainly the fee that the third-party loan servicers will charge.
Once again there are small differences or not differences at all in these values between
NBER and Doing Business for all Member States but Austria, Denmark and Poland. In
these three countries the indirect costs reported by NBER are substantially higher than the ones we use in our calculations.
We have made the assumption that the bank provisions the difference between the Gross
Book Value of the performing loan less the Gross Book Value of the non-performing
loan. If the bank has a higher provision mean it is over provisioned if the bank has a lower provision it means the bank is under provision for that NPL. Banks that are in trouble because low profitability and higher capital needs tend to be under provision,
which means they will ask for a higher price that if they were better provisioned.
Finally, our assumption for the buyer (investment fund) is that it will enter the secondary
market if it can make a profit. When the buyers of NPLs enter the market they will use
the services of third-party loan servicers. Then, the buyers of NPLs in the secondary market will take into account in their bid price the indirect costs, or costs associated with
loan servicing, and the expected profit. For the expected profit, the IRR of the external
investors (hedge funds, mutual funds, other non-bank investors, etc), we have made the
assumption that the external investors identify buying NPLs as a risky business so they
applied an excess return of 15% 111 on top of the rate of return adjusted for country risk in each country 112 . Then the IRR in each country is the sum of the excess return because of
NPL specificities + the rate of return adjusted for country risk.
Table A.4.2: Spreads in bid ask prices for NPLs in MS. Current situation
Ccy Future Lending Time to Gross recovery Gross Indirect Net Ask Buyer Bid Spread
Value rates as recover Book rate per Book costs Book expected
(EUR) of Oct (years) Value unit Value (EUR) Value rate of
2015 PL (t=0) NPL NPL return
(EUR) (EUR)
Fn i n GBVu rr GBVd ic NBVd
AT EA 100,00 1,98% 1,10 97,87 0,83 82,80 8,28 74,52 82,80 16,98% 62,92 19,88
BE EA 100,00 2,05% 0,90 98,19 0,90 89,90 3,15 86,75 89,90 17,05% 76,32 13,58
BG BG 100,00 5,14% 3,30 84,76 0,35 34,90 3,14 31,76 34,90 20,14% 19,33 15,57
CY EA 100,00 4,31% 1,50 93,87 0,73 72,80 10,56 62,24 72,80 19,31% 48,96 23,84
CZ CZ 100,00 3,10% 2,10 93,79 0,67 66,50 11,31 55,20 66,50 18,10% 38,69 27,81
DE EA 100,00 2,89% 1,20 96,64 0,84 84,40 6,75 77,65 84,40 17,89% 64,93 19,47
DK DK 100,00 1,93% 1,00 98,11 0,88 88,00 3,52 84,48 88,00 16,93% 73,19 14,81
EE EA 100,00 3,11% 3,00 91,22 0,40 40,30 3,63 36,67 40,30 18,11% 23,19 17,11
EL EA 100,00 5,09% 3,50 84,05 0,36 35,60 3,20 32,40 35,60 20,09% 19,11 16,49
ES EA 100,00 3,19% 1,50 95,40 0,78 78,30 8,61 69,69 78,30 18,19% 55,26 23,04
FI EA 100,00 3,43% 0,90 97,01 0,90 90,30 3,16 87,14 90,30 18,43% 76,78 13,52
FR EA 100,00 2,47% 1,90 95,47 0,79 78,50 7,07 71,44 78,50 17,47% 53,49 25,01
HR HR 100,00 5,28% 3,10 85,26 0,34 33,70 4,89 28,81 33,70 20,28% 17,41 16,29
HU HU 100,00 2,33% 2,00 95,50 0,43 43,00 6,24 36,77 43,00 17,33% 26,47 16,53
IE EA 100,00 5,00% 0,40 98,07 0,88 87,70 7,89 79,81 87,70 20,00% 75,25 12,45
111 This would be the premium that market investors demand for participate in the NPL secondary market on top of adjusted rate of return. This is the premium proposed for NPL external investors in the Financial Stability Review of November 2016.
112 The return adjusted for risk includes the risk free rate and the excess return adjusted for the differences in country risk observed in MS. We approximate this return adjusted for country risk as the lending rate in each MS.
IT EA 100,00 3,71% 1,80 93,65 0,64 63,90 14,06 49,84 63,90 18,71% 36,05 27,85
LT EA 100,00 3,07% 2,30 93,28 0,45 45,00 4,50 40,50 45,00 18,07% 28,42 16,58
LU EA 100,00 1,52% 2,00 97,03 0,44 43,70 6,34 37,36 43,70 16,52% 26,84 16,86
LV EA 100,00 5,24% 1,50 92,63 0,49 49,10 4,91 44,19 49,10 20,24% 35,29 13,81
MT EA 100,00 1,88% 3,00 94,57 0,41 40,70 4,07 36,63 40,70 16,88% 22,89 17,81
NL EA 100,00 3,35% 1,10 96,44 0,89 89,30 3,13 86,17 89,30 18,35% 73,81 15,49
PL PL 100,00 3,18% 3,00 91,04 0,61 60,60 9,09 51,51 60,60 18,18% 31,24 29,36
PT EA 100,00 3,67% 2,00 93,05 0,74 74,20 6,68 67,52 74,20 18,67% 49,95 24,25
RO RO 100,00 6,93% 3,30 80,16 0,34 34,40 3,61 30,79 34,40 21,93% 18,69 15,71
SE SE 100,00 1,67% 2,00 96,74 0,78 77,90 7,01 70,89 77,90 16,67% 52,15 25,75
SI EA 100,00 4,29% 0,80 96,70 0,89 89,20 3,57 85,63 89,20 19,29% 76,54 12,66
SK EA 100,00 4,89% 4,00 82,62 0,56 55,60 10,01 45,59 55,60 19,89% 22,57 33,03
UK UK 100,00 2,55% 1,00 97,51 0,89 88,60 5,32 83,28 88,60 17,55% 71,98 16,62
Average 19,22
Benchmarks
JPN 100,00 4,20% 0,6 97,56 0,921 89,85 3,77 86,08 7,71 89,85 19,20% 79,11
USA 100,00 10,00% 1,5 86,68 0,786 68,13 6,81 61,32 18,55 68,13 25,00% 49,42866
CHE 100,00 4,50% 3 87,63 0,466 40,84 1,84 39,00 46,79 40,84 19,50% 25,46992
Scenario analysis
Once we have calculated the bid-ask spread in the NPL secondary for the current situation we estimated the effect that the different policy options could have on such
spread. We distinguish between policy options that could increase the investor base and
the policy options to improve the availability of third-party loan servicers. On the other
hand, we have observed, using country data, that there is a correlation between the two
year variation in the NPL ratio ( NPL loans / total loans) and the bid ask spread.
Applying regression analysis we estimated that for 1% decrease in the bid ask spread
there is a 0.88% decrease in the NPL ratio, which means that, “ceteris paribus”, there
would be a reduction of 0.88% in the volume of NPLs every two years, or 0.44% each
year (see Annex 4.2). Our assumption is that such reduction on NPLs will increase the
volume of transactions on NPLs or NPL sales from banks to investors. To estimate the
incremental volume of NPL sales for the next two years in each MS we multiply the reduction in bid ask spread times 0.88% (this is the correlation found) and times the
volume of NPL in each country at the end of first quarter of 2017, the last available
information from ECB.
The options are: common principles, passporting and rule book for both NPL investors
and loan servicers. The next step has been to quantify such policy options in the NPL market.
Policy scenarios for NPL investors
To quantify the impact of NPL investors’ policy options on NPL market our assumption
is that such policy will contribute to reduce risk perception by investors in EU Member
States. Such reduction will occur through a convergence in the rate of return required by
investors in a market that becomes European, because of the policy measures to improve
market efficiency, therefore more efficient that those MS individual markets consider
isolated. Such reduction will contribute to reduce the bid ask spread in the NPL market
which will increase the volume of NPL transactions.
Policy option A for NPL investors is to have minimum common standards for investors
across EU Member States. To quantify the impact of such policy on NPL market our
assumption is that such policy will contribute to reduce risk perception by investors in
some EU MS, those with more entry barriers: BG, EL, IT, CY, HU, AT, PL, and RO. For
these countries our assumption under policy option A is that they will adjust their return
adjusted by country risk to the benchmark of 1.9%. The benchmark is the average
lending rate of the countries with the lowest country risk. Such reduction will contribute
to reduce the bid ask spread in the NPL market which will increase the volume of NPL
transactions.
Figure A.4.9: Lending rates as country-specific risk premium in investors' required return
Source: Commission calculations with ECB data of MFI interest rates of new lending to non-financial
corporations maturity 1-5 years in October 2015.
Policy option B for NPL investors is to implement a common passport for NPLs
investors. To quantify the impact of such policy on NPL market our assumption is that
such policy will contribute to reduce risk perception by investors, specifically in those
EU MS with country risk above the benchmark (1.9%). We assume that all the MS will
benefit of the European market framework with a reduction of 50 basis points in the rate
of return demanded by investors, besides those MS with country risk above the
benchmark will converge by 50% to the benchmark. The benchmark is the average
lending rate of the countries with the lowest country risk. Such reduction will contribute
to reduce the bid ask spread in the NPL market which will increase the volume of NPL
transactions.
Policy option C for NPL investors is to implement a common rule book for NPLs
investors. To quantify the impact of such policy on NPL market our assumption is that
such policy will contribute to reduce risk perception by investors, such that the worst
performers will adjust their rate of return to the benchmark but at the same time the best
performers will also adjust to the benchmark which will penalize then. We assume that
all the MS will benefit of the European market framework with a reduction of 50 basis points in the rate of return demanded by investors, besides those MS with country risk
above the benchmark will converge by 50% to the benchmark whereas those MS below
the benchmark will move to the benchmark reducing the distance by 25%. The
benchmark is the average lending rate of the countries with the lowest country risk. Such
reduction will contribute to reduce the bid ask spread in the NPL market which will increase the volume of NPL transactions.
Table A.4.3: Changes in Spreads in bid ask prices for different policy scenarios in NPL markets (convergence loan
rates)
Current New Change incremental New Change incremental New Chang incrementa spread spread if A in NPL sales spread if in NPL sales spread if in l NPL Spread (billion €) B Spread (billion €) C Spread sales (billion €)
AT EA 19,88 19,86 -0,02 0,00 19,52 -0,36 0,08 19,52 -0,36 0,08
BE EA 13,58 13,58 0,00 0,00 13,23 -0,35 0,07 13,23 -0,35 0,07
BG BG 15,57 14,89 -0,67 0,03 14,21 -1,36 0,06 14,21 -1,36 0,06
CY EA 23,84 23,24 -0,60 0,12 22,55 -1,30 0,27 22,55 -1,30 0,27
CZ CZ 27,81 27,81 0,00 0,00 26,82 -0,99 0,06 26,82 -0,99 0,06
DE EA 19,47 19,47 0,00 0,13 18,74 -0,73 0,41 18,74 -0,73 0,41
DK DK 14,81 14,81 0,00 0,00 14,47 -0,34 0,05 14,47 -0,34 0,05
EE EA 17,11 17,11 0,00 0,00 16,35 -0,77 0,00 16,35 -0,77 0,00
EL EA 16,49 15,79 -0,70 0,70 15,07 -1,42 1,43 15,07 -1,42 1,43
ES EA 23,04 23,04 0,00 0,00 22,10 -0,94 1,12 22,10 -0,94 1,12
FI EA 13,52 13,52 0,00 0,00 12,75 -0,78 0,03 12,75 -0,78 0,03
FR EA 25,01 25,01 0,00 0,00 24,23 -0,78 1,03 24,23 -0,78 1,03
HR HR 16,29 16,29 0,00 0,00 14,98 -1,31 0,06 14,98 -1,31 0,06
HU HU 16,53 16,45 -0,08 0,00 16,12 -0,40 0,02 16,12 -0,40 0,02
IE EA 12,45 12,45 0,00 0,00 11,88 -0,58 0,18 11,88 -0,58 0,18
IT EA 27,85 27,39 -0,46 1,20 26,77 -1,09 2,85 26,77 -1,09 2,85
LT EA 16,58 16,58 0,00 0,00 15,87 -0,71 0,01 15,87 -0,71 0,01
LU EA 16,86 16,86 0,00 0,00 16,58 -0,29 0,01 16,69 -0,18 0,01
LV EA 13,81 13,81 0,00 0,00 12,69 -1,11 0,01 12,69 -1,11 0,01
MT EA 17,81 17,81 0,00 0,00 17,47 -0,35 0,00 17,47 -0,34 0,00
NL EA 15,49 15,49 0,00 0,00 14,61 -0,89 0,35 14,61 -0,89 0,35
PL PL 29,36 28,92 -0,44 0,06 28,17 -1,19 0,16 28,17 -1,19 0,16
PT EA 24,25 24,25 0,00 0,00 22,91 -1,35 0,53 22,91 -1,35 0,53
RO RO 15,71 14,67 -1,03 0,06 13,78 -1,92 0,11 13,78 -1,92 0,11
SE SE 25,75 25,75 0,00 0,00 25,24 -0,51 0,05 25,36 -0,39 0,04
SI EA 12,66 12,66 0,00 0,00 11,74 -0,92 0,03 11,74 -0,92 0,03
SK EA 33,03 33,03 0,00 0,00 30,77 -2,26 0,04 30,77 -2,26 0,04
UK UK 16,62 16,62 0,00 0,00 16,08 -0,55 0,38 16,08 -0,55 0,38
Total 2,32 9,40 9,38
Policy scenarios for loan servicers
To quantify the impact of NPL investors’ policy options on loan servicers market our
assumption is that such policy will contribute to increase the number of third-party loan
servicers in MS which we associate with a reduction in the barriers of entry and in the
costs of providing loan servicing. Such reduction will occur through a convergence in the
cost of servicing that will improve market efficiency, therefore more efficient that those
MS individual markets consider isolated. Such reduction will contribute to reduce the bid
ask spread in the NPL market which will increase the volume of NPL transactions.
Policy option A for NPL investors is to have minimum common standards for loan
servicers across EU MS. To quantify the impact of such policy on NPL market our
assumption is that such policy will contribute to reduce servicer costs in some EU MS,
those with more barriers: EL,IT,CY and AT. For these MS our assumption under policy
option A is that they will be able to adjust their cost by 10%. Such reduction will
contribute to reduce the bid ask spread in the NPL market which will increase the volume
of NPL transactions.
Policy option B for NPL investors is to implement a common passport for loan servicers.
To quantify the impact of such policy on NPL market our assumption is that such policy
will contribute to reduce loan-servicing costs by 10% in all countries due to the higher
size of the market and those MS with cost above the benchmark will close the gap by
50%. The best performers MS in terms of cost will be able to keep such advantage. The
benchmark is the average cost among those countries with the best cost records. Such
reduction will contribute to reduce the bid ask spread in the NPL market which will
increase the volume of NPL transactions.
Figure A.4.10: Indirect costs of loan recovery as indicator of costs of loan servicing
Source: Commission calculations with World Bank Doing Business 2016 data of insolvency – cost of
recovery in %.
Policy option C for NPL investors is to implement a common rule book for loan
servicers. To quantify the impact of such policy on NPL market our assumption is that
such policy will contribute to reduce loan-servicing costs by 10% in all countries due to
the higher size of the market and the cost gap between each country and the benchmark
will close the gap 50%. The best performers MS in terms of cost will suffer an increase
in their cost due to the convergence to the benchmark. The benchmark is the average cost among those countries with the best cost records. The reduction in costs will contribute
to reduce the bid ask spread in the NPL market which will increase the volume of NPL
transactions.
Table A.4.4: Changes in Spreads in bid ask prices for different policy scenarios in NPL markets (convergence costs)
Current New incremental New Change incremental New Change incremental spread spread if
Change in spread in NPL sales A Spread
NPL sales
(billion €) spread if B in Spread
NPL sales (billion €) if C Spread (billion €)
AT EA 19,88 19,05 -0,83 0,18 18,64 -1,24 0,27 18,64 -1,24 0,27
BE EA 13,58 13,58 0,00 0,00 13,27 -0,31 0,06 14,51 0,92 -0,18
BG BG 15,57 15,57 0,00 0,00 15,25 -0,31 0,01 15,25 -0,31 0,01
CY EA 23,84 22,79 -1,06 0,22 20,79 -3,06 0,64 20,79 -3,06 0,64
CZ CZ 27,81 27,81 0,00 0,00 24,02 -3,79 0,24 24,02 -3,79 0,24
DE EA 19,47 19,47 0,00 0,00 18,79 -0,68 0,38 19,00 -0,46 0,26
DK DK 14,81 14,81 0,00 0,00 14,46 -0,35 0,05 15,56 0,75 -0,11
EE EA 17,11 17,11 0,00 0,00 16,75 -0,36 0,00 16,75 -0,36 0,00
EL EA 16,49 16,17 -0,32 0,32 16,17 -0,32 0,32 16,17 -0,32 0,32
ES EA 23,04 23,04 0,00 0,00 21,39 -1,64 1,96 21,39 -1,64 1,96
FI EA 13,52 13,52 0,00 0,00 13,21 -0,32 0,01 14,45 0,93 -0,04
FR EA 25,01 25,01 0,00 0,00 24,30 -0,71 0,93 24,30 -0,71 0,93
HR HR 16,29 16,29 0,00 0,00 14,87 -1,42 0,07 14,87 -1,42 0,07
HU HU 16,53 16,53 0,00 0,00 14,72 -1,81 0,11 14,72 -1,81 0,11
IE EA 12,45 12,45 0,00 0,00 11,67 -0,79 0,25 11,67 -0,79 0,25
IT EA 27,85 26,44 -1,41 3,69 22,29 -5,56 14,59 22,29 -5,56 14,59
LT EA 16,58 16,58 0,00 0,00 15,90 -0,68 0,01 15,90 -0,68 0,01
LU EA 16,86 16,86 0,00 0,00 15,03 -1,84 0,06 15,03 -1,84 0,06
LV EA 13,81 13,81 0,00 0,00 13,07 -0,74 0,01 13,07 -0,74 0,01
MT EA 17,81 17,81 0,00 0,00 17,20 -0,61 0,01 17,20 -0,61 0,01
NL EA 15,49 15,49 0,00 0,00 15,18 -0,31 0,12 16,41 0,92 -0,36
PL PL 29,36 29,36 0,00 0,00 26,63 -2,73 0,36 26,63 -2,73 0,36
PT EA 24,25 24,25 0,00 0,00 23,58 -0,67 0,26 23,58 -0,67 0,26
RO RO 15,71 15,71 0,00 0,00 15,09 -0,62 0,03 15,09 -0,62 0,03
SE SE 25,75 25,75 0,00 0,00 25,05 -0,70 0,07 25,05 -0,70 0,07
SI EA 12,66 12,66 0,00 0,00 12,30 -0,36 0,01 13,42 0,76 -0,02
SK EA 33,03 33,03 0,00 0,00 29,53 -3,50 0,06 29,53 -3,50 0,06
UK UK 16,62 16,62 0,00 0,00 16,09 -0,53 0,37 16,75 0,13 -0,09
Total 4,41 21,27 19,74
Extension of the policy scenarios
Additionally, we have consider the improvement in the time to recover the defaulted
loans because of these policies or even because other initiatives on NPLs, for instance
AECE. As a reduction in the time to recover loans favours the shrinkage of bid-ask spread, we have estimated the incremental volumes of NPL sales if time to recover adjusts to the values proposed in the AECE Impact assessment.
Table A.4.5: Changes in spread in time to recover adjust ACE
Current spread New spread if time to recover ACE Change in Spread incremental NPL sales (billion €)
AT 19,88 19,88 0,00 0,00
BE 13,58 13,58 0,00 0,00
BG 15,57 12,70 -2,87 0,13
CY 23,84 23,84 0,00 0,00
CZ 27,81 25,73 -2,08 0,13
DE 19,47 19,47 0,00 0,00
DK 14,81 14,81 0,00 0,00
EE 17,11 14,44 -2,67 0,01
EL 16,49 13,30 -3,19 3,21
ES 23,04 23,04 0,00 0,00
FI 13,52 13,52 0,00 0,00
FR 25,01 23,33 -1,68 2,22
HR 16,29 13,78 -2,51 0,12
HU 16,53 15,62 -0,91 0,05
IE 12,45 12,45 0,00 0,00
IT 27,85 26,83 -1,03 2,69
LT 16,58 14,74 -1,84 0,01
LU 16,86 15,70 -1,16 0,04
LV 13,81 13,81 0,00 0,00
MT 17,81 15,09 -2,72 0,02
NL 15,49 15,49 0,00 0,00
PL 29,36 25,34 -4,02 0,53
PT 24,25 22,70 -1,55 0,61
RO 15,71 12,91 -2,80 0,16
SE 25,75 24,10 -1,65 0,17
SI 12,66 12,66 0,00 0,00
SK 33,03 27,11 -5,92 0,10
UK 16,62 16,62 0,00 0,00
Total 10,22
Besides, we have estimated the incremental volumes of NPL sales if option A for NPL investors and option B for loan servicers would be adopted at the same time with and
without taking into account the improvement in the time to recover the non-performing
loans.
Table A.4.6. Changes in Spread if apply scenario a for NPL investors and scenario b for Loan servicers
Current spread New spread NPL Change in incremental NPL sales new spread A+B Change in incremental scenario A + Loan Spread (billion €) plus reduction Spread NPL sales servicers escenario B time to recover (billion €) AECE
AT 19,88 18,62 -1,26 0,28 18,62 -1,26 0,28
BE 13,58 12,92 -0,67 0,13 12,92 -0,67 0,13
BG 15,57 13,89 -1,67 0,08 11,28 -4,29 0,20
CY 23,84 19,49 -4,36 0,91 19,49 -4,36 0,91
CZ 27,81 23,03 -4,78 0,30 21,05 -6,75 0,43
DE 19,47 18,06 -1,41 0,79 18,06 -1,41 0,79
DK 14,81 14,12 -0,69 0,10 14,12 -0,69 0,10
EE 17,11 15,98 -1,13 0,00 13,43 -3,68 0,01
EL 16,49 14,75 -1,74 1,75 11,83 -4,65 4,69
ES 23,04 20,45 -2,58 3,08 20,45 -2,58 3,08
FI 13,52 12,43 -1,09 0,04 12,43 -1,09 0,04
FR 25,01 23,53 -1,48 1,96 21,91 -3,10 4,09
HR 16,29 13,56 -2,72 0,13 11,29 -4,99 0,25
HU 16,53 14,32 -2,21 0,13 13,44 -3,09 0,18
IE 12,45 11,09 -1,36 0,44 11,09 -1,36 0,44
IT 27,85 21,21 -6,64 17,43 20,25 -7,60 19,94
LT 16,58 15,20 -1,38 0,01 13,45 -3,13 0,02
LU 16,86 14,74 -2,12 0,07 13,61 -3,26 0,11
LV 13,81 11,96 -1,85 0,02 11,96 -1,85 0,02
MT 17,81 16,86 -0,96 0,01 14,19 -3,62 0,03
NL 15,49 14,30 -1,20 0,47 14,30 -1,20 0,47
PL 29,36 25,44 -3,92 0,52 21,61 -7,75 1,03
PT 24,25 22,24 -2,01 0,80 20,79 -3,46 1,37
RO 15,71 13,17 -2,54 0,14 10,73 -4,97 0,28
SE 25,75 24,54 -1,21 0,13 22,93 -2,82 0,29
SI 12,66 11,38 -1,28 0,04 11,38 -1,28 0,04
SK 33,03 27,27 -5,76 0,10 21,79 -11,24 0,19
UK 16,62 15,54 -1,08 0,74 15,54 -1,08 0,74
Total 30,60 40,15
Conclusions
Instead of a conclusion, a word of caution is warranted. The outcome of the simulations with the pricing model is assumption-driven. The coefficients obtained in the crosscountry analysis suffer from unsatisfying data and a very small number of observations. Hence, there are good reason to challenge each step in the simulations exercise and the results serve only to illustrate the issues and may help assess the relative performance of the different policy options rather than be taken as a guidance on how NPL markets can actually develop.
-
4.T RANSLATING THE SCORES FOR THE ASSESSMENT CRITERIA INTO AN OVERALL
RANKING OF THE POLICY OPTIONS
The Table below summarises the ranking of the different policy options in Table 6, Table
7, and Table 8.
Table A.4.7: Summary of options and their effects
Baseline non-binding Directive with Regulation with fully common common standards harmonised rules and principles and use of passports common market supervision
NPL investors 1.Address failures in (national) NPL markets stimulates entry into
MS with high entry 0 + ++ +++
barriers incentivises smaller
firms to enter 0 + +++ +++
2.Foster a single NPL market equal treatment across
MS 0 0 ++ +++
incentivises entry of
firms from outside the 0 + ++ ++
EU
realises scale effects 0 0 0 0
-
3.Safeguards for borrower rights Ensure efficient
supervision 0 - -- ---
Costs of adjustment of
laws that protect 0 - -- ---
borrower rights Loan Servicers
-
1.Address failures in (national) NPL markets stimulates entry into
MS with high entry 0 + ++ +++
barriers incentivises smaller
firms to enter 0 + ++ ++
-
2.Foster a single NPL market equal treatment across
MS 0 0 ++ +++
incentivises entry of
firms from outside the 0 + ++ +++
EU
realises scale effects 0 ++ +++ +++
-
3.Safeguards for borrower rights Ensure efficient
supervision 0 - -- ---
Costs of adjustment of
laws that protect 0 - -- ---
borrower rights
An overall ranking of effectiveness was derived by averaging the sum of plusses for investors and servicers. Efficiency is the difference of effectiveness and the average sum
of minuses for investors and servicers.
Table A.4.8: numerical results for effectiveness and efficiency
Baseline Option 1 – Non-binding Option 2 – Minimum principles standards
Effectiveness 0 8/2=4 20/2=10 Efficiency 0 4-2=2 10-4=6
Finally, a + is allocated for a score in the range 1 to 4, ++ in the range 5-8, +++ in the
range 9-12.
Table A.4.9: Scoring for effectiveness and efficiency
Baseline Option 1 – Non-binding Option 2 – Minimum principles standards
Effectiveness 0 + (score 4) +++ (score 10) Efficiency 0 + (score 2) ++ (score 6)
A NNEX 5: M ARKET OVERVIEW
-
1.N ATURE AND SIZE OF THE NPL MARKET
Fragmentation of market and legal conditions along the increases entry costs especially for international investors. Though there have been numerous transactions in NPLs in the EU in the last years, there is no single market for NPLs, but fragmented early stage national markets. This section reviews the available data on NPL transactions and puts them in perspective. A more comprehensive review of market conditions can be found in Bruegel (2017).
Absent public data collections, the only available numbers of NPL transactions stem from publications of consultancy firms. These collect data from public sources and may also use information from their business relationships. They report that they cannot guarantee accuracy of the data and the observation of discrepancies between data coming from different consultancies underlines the difficulty to keep track of NPL markets. Commission research on NPL transactions found that only few and large transactions are reported in main media. Smaller transactions are reported on specialised websites, but often lack details about buyer, seller and/or amounts (see also Annex 4.2).
Between 2014 and 2017, consultancies recorded transaction volumes between 100 and 150 billion EUR per annum in secondary markets for loans in the EU. 113 The consultancies that collect data do not provide information about the share of NPLs in loan sales. The three approaches presented in Annex 4.2 suggest that the average share of NPL in loan sales could be 70 to 80%. The charts below indicate the evolution of loan transactions across the main EU markets by various sources.
Box A.5.1: Caveats on the data on NPL sales
There is no official statistics on transactions data of NPLs. Official documents regularly quote data from consultancies, which report data in publications or on websites. These consultancies cannot scrutinise the data quality as rigorously as statistical offices could do. Moreover, a number of data limitations may distort the information content Bruegel 2017 lists the following:
One cannot differentiate between non-performing assets and other non-core assets. If a bank sells NPLs, the transaction might be so structured that it still retains exposure to
the loan.
Buyers may be other banks, so that the NPLs remain in the banking sector. Non-banks may re-sell NPLs, so that the transaction volume does not reduce the NPL
ratio of the banking sector. Moreover, details of transactions are not disclosed in several cases. Sometimes the buyer, seller and/or volumes are not made public. The data collectors' different strategies to circumvent this limitation may be accountable for difference in the statistics.
113 The number is measured in book values (unpaid primary balance) and is comparable to the amount banks can free from their balance sheet. Since prices are much lower than 100%, both transaction values and invested amounts by non-banks are also smaller.
Figure A.5.1: Transaction volumes on loan markets, sum of 2015 and 2016 in billion of EUR
Source: AFME (2017), Deloitte (2017a, 2017b), PWC(2017).
The NPL market has been highly concentrated. The breakdown of transactions by country suggests strong variation, with a strong clustering in four countries: ES, IE, IT
and the UK. In the former three NPL sales contributed substantially to reduced high NPL
ratios. There have been few transactions In other countries with high NPL ratios (CY,EL, PT, RO, SI) and sizeable market activity in countries with low NPL ratios (UK, DE, NL).
In CEEC, markets for NPLs seem emerging, but are still at infant stage. 114 The 10 largest
transactions in 2015/16 accounted for one third of the transaction volume, while the other
two third was distributed over about 480 transactions. Very few transactions were
recorded with a volume below EUR 100 million. 115
Of the 103 banks that disclosed transactions, about 40 had multiple transactions. NAMA
and SAREB, the Irish respectively Spanish asset management company were the most important sellers. The loan portfolios banks sell cover very different asset classes and
according to market sources some buyers are specialised in specific asset classes. The
figure below gives a snapshot of market shares by asset class based from a sample of 365 NPL transactions signed in 2015-2017.
The share of loans owed by consumers is unknown because loans are sold in large
portfolios, which are often mixed and do not allow to calculate a breakdown by
counterpart. The share was at least 11% according to AFME (2017), see Figure A.5.2. 116
114 See Deloitte (2017).
115 Around 10% in our sample.
116 See Figure A.5.2 in Annex 5.
n banks’ balance sheets, about a third of the NPL had consumers as counterpart. 117 There is little data bout the breakdown into consumer credit and mortgages 118 , i.e. those
being regulated through the Consumer Credit Directive and the Mortgage Credit Directive. 119 Since consumer credits are smaller, NPL purchaser are more likely to outsource their management to loan servicing firms.
Figure A.5.2: Loan sales by underlying loan category
Consumers, SME, retail
Corporate
Commercial real estate
Residential
Secured loans
Unsecured
other
Source: COM calculations with KPMG data, which is retrieved from publicly available sources.
On the buyer side, there are about 120 debt managers that invest in distressed debt in North America and Europe. 120 In Europe, almost 40% of the transaction deals was accountable to the biggest five buyers. More than 20 of the active investors were large
investment funds with a market share of almost 50%. 121 Most buyers are investment
firms, but also a few banks bought loans. 122
Table A.5.1: Largest investors in distressed debt (Source: Prequin)
Firm origin Total Funds Raised in Estimated Dry Powder Last 10 Years ($mn) ($mn)
Fortress Investment Group USA 15842 6884
GSO Capital Partners USA 19403 4970
117 34.8% in 2016 according to ECB data.
118 Mortgage loans to households were EUR 4189 billion at end 2016 and credit for consumption o households 1049 billion, without, however a breakdown into performing and non-performing loans available in ECB statistics. In Portugal, the NPL ratio of mortgages was 6.7% and that of consumer credit NPLs at 10% according to European Commission (2017c).
119 Directive 2008/48/EC i and Directive 2014/17 i.
120 Prequin special report: Distressed debt in North America and Europe. 2016.
121 See Brugel (2017).
122 In our sample 15 banks accounting for 12% of the transaction volume.
Centerbridge Capital Partners USA 17640 4724
Sankaty Advisors USA 13184 3595
Oaktree Capital Management USA 55686 3590
CarVal Investors USA 13968 2499
Avenue Capital Group USA 19041 2133
Castlelake USA 4269 1999
Catalyst Capital Group CND 3269 1967
Cerberus Capital Management USA 9329 1923
The table below breaks down investors into EU NPLs by the amount of national markets they were active in. The dominant number of investment firms was active in only one market and a few concentrated on 2 or three markets. The small number of investment firms active on four or more markets accounted for about a third of all transactions.
Table A.5.3: The geographical reach of NPL investors
Number of Member States number of number of average transaction size in invested in firms transactions million EUR
>4 11 110 573.3
3 5 28 756.3
2 10 65 503.0
1 85 116 616.6 Source: COM calculations with KPMG data, which is retrieved from publicly available sources.
Table A.5.4. Main European NPL investors and key company figures
Number of countries Company where it of which Operating name HQ operates EU income/revenue EBITDA total assets
B2 Holding NO 23 20 125.23 143.24 630.88
Eos Group DE 26 677.56 226.61 1 526.34
Kruk Group PL 9 9 185.98 86.07 734.92
Hoist Group SE 11 11 225.60 293.27 1 922.65
Intrum SE 23 23 611.24 329.61 1 446.16
Axactor NO 5 4 38.88 -0.01 271.89
BancaIFIS IT 1 1 237.69 66.27 4 995.60
Idea Fimit IT 1 1
LCM Partners UK 10 10
APS group LU 11 11 26.26 10.17 40.88 2016 numbers in million EUR. Company numbers relate to the total group, not its NPL business.
Source: Company annual reports 2016.
Though not all NPL buyers have been investment funds, they represent a sizeable market share. As regards the potential investor base for NPL, it is interesting to identify investment funds that specialised in comparable products. The table below shows the free capacity debt investment funds had, using a mathematical approach to allocate the known data about geographical focus and product focus to the individual cells. The approach shows that distressed debt investors in North America have almost two times investment capacity than European investors. Other asset classes are smaller and also more dissimilar to NPLs.
Table A.5.6: Estimated dry powder of investment funds specialised in private debt strategies, billion EUR 2017H.
Direct Venture Distressed Lending Mezzanine Debt Debt Special Situations known total
North America 47.1 39.4 1.3 51.8 17.7 157.3
Europe 19.3 16.2 0.5 21.3 7.3 64.6
Asia 3.1 2.6 0.1 3.5 1.2 10.5
Rest of World 0.5 0.5 0.0 0.6 0.2 1.8
known total 70.1 58.7 1.9 77.1 26.4 234.2
Source: Commission calculations with Preqin data using the entropy approach. 123
Price data is usually not disclosed and some cases are reported that deals were aborted because banks and prospective buyers could not agree on the price. If prices are lower than what banks provisioned they realise a loss, which reduces their capital and therefore inhibits their incentive to enter into a sales' deal. These coverage ratios differ strongly across banks, being smaller in small than in large banks and stand at around 44% at the
EU aggregate level. 124 Hence, for a price lower than 56% (100% - 44%), the "average"
bank would have to record a loss. There is a perception that EU banks may underprovision their NPLs, derived from the observation that US coverage ratios were about
20 percentage points higher. 125
The figure below shows average prices of NPL portfolio transaction taken from a consultancy publication. It demonstrates that prices vary strongly depending on the type of debt and the quality of the underlying collateral.
Figure A.5.3: Average price on face value of NPL portfolio transactions
123 Measured as dry powder, which consists of capital raised, capital committed and capital raised in the past, but not yet deployed.
124 See FSC report, section 2.2.2.
125 See IMF euro area selected issues 2015.
Source: AFME (2017) quoting PWC data.
More information needs to rely on transactions reported in the press. For few selected transactions, media or analytical reports quote or derive price data. For example, Unicredit's sale of 17 billion EUR NPLs to PIMCO in August 2017 was reported to have
yielded 13% 126 , MPS sale of junior NPL tranches to the Atlante II fund at 21% 127 , Carlites purchase of 900 million from Caixabank in 2015 at 25% 128 , Algebris reportedly paid 35% for a secured 750 million EUR NPL portfolio from Italian Banco BPM in
2017, 129 Axactor revealed it bought several portfolios of Spanish consumer loans between 6 and 7% in March 2016. 130 For comparison, the FDIC, which is the public
institution in the USA in charge or resolving banks, realised 8-30% sales price relative to book value on NPLs (see Table A.5.7).
Table A.5.7: Prices on secondary markets for loans in the USA
126 https://www.reuters.com/article/us-italy-banks-unicredit-npl-idUSKBN1A21SU 127 IMF Global market monitor on 5 July 2017
128 https://www.copernicusservicing.com/goldman-sach-cleans-caixabank/ 129 https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2017-06-09/algebris-said-to-be-winning-bidder-in-banco
href="https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2017-06-09/algebris-said-to-be-winning-bidder-in-banco-bpm-bad-loan-sale">bpm-bad-loan-sale 130 http://epub.artbox.no/axactor/ar2016eng/#14/z
FDIC loan sales (USD values in million)
2016
Loan Type Book Appraised Sales % of % of Value Value Price # Sold SP/BV SP/AV
Performing $1.60 $1.02 $1.30 11 81.25% 127.45%
Non-performing $15.74 $1.72 $1.28 16 8.13% 74.42%
Total 2016 $27.76 $6.31 $6.40 135 23.06% 101.43%
2015
Performing $347.59 $170.89 $236.91 2,904 68.16% 138.63%
Non-performing $402.34 $107.06 $110.61 2,666 27.49% 103.32%
Total 2015 $1,724.13 $717.45 $686.85 11,187 39.84% 95.74%
2014
Performing $197.94 $124.42 $133.90 1163 67.65% 107.62%
Non-performing $309.80 $66.62 $64.40 577 20.79% 96.67%
Total 2014 $771.64 $309.54 $321.63 2,499 41.68% 103.91%
2013 Performing $53.80 $33.99 $37.00 589 68.77% 108.86% Non-performing $43.21 $12.56 $14.60 177 33.79% 116.24% Total 2013 $259.88 $98.38 $109.96 1,555 42.31% 111.77%
2012 Performing $497.2 $265.35 $378.81 3621 76.19% 142.76% Non-performing $123.45 $31.19 $37.43 768 30.32% 120.01%
Total 2012 $1,108.63 $504.29 $672.42 7,801 60.65% 133.34%
Note: Totals include sales of portfolios consisting of subperforming and non-performing loans.
Source: FDIC
For some debt funds, profitability numbers are available. The number is however small, especially for funds with a geographical focus on Europe. According to the data available, average and median profitability was a bit higher in Europe than in America. At the polar spectrum of the distribution, differences in profitability are more pronounced, with low-profitability European investments being relatively more profitable
than American ones and vice versa for high-profitability investments 131 .
131 The term "Investments" is here used for the geographical focus.
Table A.5.8: Profitability in % of investment funds Figure A.5.4: Distribution of profitability of investment specialised in distressed debt with a focus on either funds specialised in distressed debt
America Europe average 11.1 11.6 median 10.7 12.1 weighted average 10.9 10.5 Observations 69 18 missing observations 31 8
Note: Profitability measure is the net internal rate of return of the latest available observation. In most cases 2017Q2. Missing observations are those funds for which no profitability number was displayed. Source: Commission calculations with Preqin data.
Box A.5.2: Other determinants of the bid-ask gap Market practitioners signalled other factors that cause a high bid ask spread in NPL transactions. 1
Different discount rates: As required by IAS 39, banks use the effective interest rate on the loans. Investors use their required returns, which typically exceed 15%. Administrative expenditure: Banks use administrative expenses and servicing fees in their financial statement of the year in which they are incurred while investors deduct such costs from the value when they calculate the net present value. Reputational effects: Banks attach an extra value to loans from debtors, which whom they have a long-term business relationship. They may not want to undermine the reputation they had built up with customers important to them. Poor data quality on loans and incomplete information on collateral value. Non-bank investors need to spend resources in understanding the value of the NPL portfolio that is for sale. Costs of capital and taxation. Non-banks may have higher costs of funding and be exposed to extra costs linked to the transfer of the loan such as for registration. As regards the underlying information asymmetry as genuine reason for high bid-ask spreads, several mechanisms have emerged endogenously to reduce their importance. Market participants signalled that the outlook for repeated transactions creates an incentive for banks to fairly represent the value of the loans they offer for purchase. Collateralisation of loans also helps because it puts a floor on the value of loans, provided the potential buyer is able to ascribe a value to the collateral. 1 Still, market participants flagged in the public consultation that data issues are a very important concern for them. A specific workstream in the NPL Action Plan is meant to address this issue.
A further mechanism in addition to information asymmetries is that consultancy firms or other intermediaries bring together potential buyers and sellers. They assist in assessing the value of the portfolio by scrutinising loans, collateral and data quality. They invest their reputation to overcome the effect of information asymmetry and contribute to reducing the spread between bid and supply so that demand and supply can meet. They also have an indispensable role because of their knowledge of past deals to which they contributed, which means these are the only players that have some kind of market overview of prices, loan quality, collateral and other conditions.
The involvement of specialised information intermediaries does not totally reduce the bid-ask spread as they charge a fee for their services. Moreover, intermediation does not mean that
market functioning is imitated. Intermediaries and big potential investors have an incentive to limit competitive pressure in order to benefit from a positive bid-ask spread and the scope to
exploit the pressure on banks to sell, respectively.
-
2.N ATURE AND SIZE OF THE L OAN SERVICING MARKET
About 40 groups with 100 firms are in this business line in the EU, some of them are
present in different countries, others are small or specialised in specific portfolios such as
real estate and combine loan servicing with other related activities. Market reports
witness a sizeable number of acquisitions in the loan servicing market in the last years, some from NPL investors. Some big loan servicers entered the business of buying loans. 132
While there are some loan servicing firms that act in different Member States, they focus
on countries with already sufficient demand for loan sales. Moreover, their main entry or
expansion strategy has apparently been the acquisition of existing national loan servicers,
implying that expansion to a new market is difficult without national incumbents already present. For selecting loan servicers, potential NPL buyers can rely on the advice of consultancies, the ranking of around 30 firms done by S&P 133 , or loan servicers also active in the USA. 134
What are loan servicers and what do they do?
During the life of a loan one can distinguish three different roles from the lender
perspective: Loan originators, Loan owners and Loan servicers. These three roles can be
play within the same institution (company) or by different companies. The scenarios
where these three lender roles split in different combinations are those where a portfolio
of loans is securitized or when the loan originator sells or outsources a portfolio of defaulted or non-performing loans (NPLs).
Loan servicing is the administration of a loan or portfolio of loans from the time the
proceeds are dispersed until the loan is paid off. Loan servicing business combines two
lines of business: transaction processing and administration of defaulted loans.
Transaction processing would benefit from economies of scale because can easily be
automatized. However, the administration of defaulted loans needs a balance between automated defaulted loans (default management) and "hands on" default loans. The first
option leads to foreclose whereas in the hands on procedure there is a loss mitigation goal
that requires significant trained manpower. Loss mitigation includes loan restructuring,
accepting a deed in lieu of foreclosure or approving a short sale.
132 E.g. Hoist, Kruk Group.
133 Standards & Poors: EMEA Servicer Evaluation Industry Report 2016.
134 The US Mortgage Bankers Association ranks loan servicing firms including a short list of firms that serve non-US loans (11 entries). A few loan servicers activity in Europe are on this list including Situs, CBRE loan services, Wells Fargo.
Loan servicing services include: sending monthly payment statements and collecting monthly payments, borrower billing, payment posting, collection and loan accounting,
calculation of borrower interest and fees, set up and management of bank account
structures to effect dominion of cash, generation of borrower notices, payoff letters and
amortization schedules, maintaining records of payments and balances, collecting and
paying taxes and insurance (and managing escrow and impound funds ), remitting funds to the note holder, and following up on delinquencies. Additionally they may also offer
their services for: pricing loans, helping borrowers who default on their loans through
loss mitigation options, due diligence advisory on the credit portfolio for disposals and
acquisitions, recovery, collateral performance, foreclosure litigation, manage foreclosed
properties, collateral reporting for lender credit analysis purposes, financial and collateral reporting tracking, property inspections and real estate evaluation, commercialization and
sales.
Loan servicers' revenues come from the servicing fee. This fee can be either a fixed
percentage of the unpaid primary balance (UPB) of the underlying loan, ancillary fees for
late payment or loan modification, or interest earned on principal and interest and taxes
and insurance collected by the servicer before distribution.
There are in-house and third-party loan servicers, depending on whether the loans are
serviced by the loan originator or by an external company. The latter is common when a
portfolio of non-performing loans is managed. Besides, they are label as captive loan
servicers when the loan service firm is owned by the loan originator or by the loan owner, or if they have a unique client or their portfolio is owned mainly by one loan
originator.
It is also common to distinguish between primary servicers, if the loan servicer manages
performing loans, special servicers, if the loan servicer manages NPLs, or master services
if loan servicer monitors a sub-servicer activity. Master servicers are responsible for the
oversight of primary servicers. Furthermore, loan servicers tend to manage three asset classes, specialising in one of them or any combination of the three: asset finance,
residential mortgages and commercial mortgages.
Federal Reserve Board et al. (2016) identifies two risks on loan servicers: business risk
that can include legal compliance and reputational risk (due to regulations, including
consumer protections) and valuation risk that refers to the firm's ability to estimate a value for its mortgage servicing activities and it is driven by interest rate and default risk.
Box A.5.3: The economic value added of loan servicers
It is debatable whether moving debt administration from a bank to a third-party loan servicer
yields economic benefits beyond addressing moral hazard issues which are present in a situation where the loan originating bank maintains the loan servicing. It does not hold in general that
third-party loan servicers can extract more value from a portfolio of loans than a bank can. 135
Administering an NPL portfolio is more costly than one of performing loans since it requires
follow-up action such as sending letters and notices, entering into negotiations about debt
rescheduling or taking legal enforcement action. Data from the US suggests that the servicing of non-performing mortgage loans costs about 13 times more than that of performing loans. 136 High NPLs bind bank operating resources and potentially prevent banks from carrying out more
productive uses. This effect is particularly material in smaller banks having less specialised staff.
Larger banks tend to have separate business entities to keep costs under control whereas smaller
banks often have no capacity to do so.
A number of circumstances are listed below where NPL administration could be done effectively or/and efficiently by third-party servicers:
Non-bank firms sometimes specialise in this administration, realise scale effects in IT and
may resort to restructuring loans to increase the recovery value by re-negotiating payment
terms and maturities. 137 Some loan servicing firms claim to increase recovery rates through cooperation and striving for amicable solutions. 138
If non-bank investors have higher willingness to take risks to banks, and as not being subject
to bank regulation, or if they have special expertise in assessing particular market segments
such as commercial real estate loans, SME loans or ship loans, they can contribute to a potentially higher valuation of NPLs than banks would. Some firms combine loan servicing
with other services such as administration of commercial real estate.
Loan servicing firms may also specialise in loan enforcement through out-of court or judicial
action and benefit from either specialised legal expertise or from a longer time horizon than
banks have available. Reputation effects may also impact on recovery because either the loan
135 Banks may draw advantage from conducting loan servicing in view of future loan contracts with the debtor or may find it easier to restructure loans with customers with which they hold a longterm relationship. Compared to market financing, banks have a comparative advantage in screening credit performance, but this unlikely holds for all banks and vis-a-vis firms specialised in this activity. This consideration, however, may explain why banks have an interest in keeping some NPLs on their balance sheets and also attach a higher valuation to these than external investors without interest in the long-term credit relationship would do.
136 Data from the US mortgage bankers association quoted in Federal Reserve Board et al. (2016) reveal that average servicing costs of performing loans were 175 USD and those of nonperforming loans 2375 USD in 2015. From the accounts of a European firm specialised in acquiring non-performing consumer loans, one can derive collection costs of about 14% of interest collected.
137 ESRB (2017) argues that bankers have a comparative advantage in borrower relations and customer service, but not necessarily with respect to NPL resolution. Private equity and asset management firms can specialise in the operational and/or financial restructuring of viable borrowers and the maximisation of collateral value collection.
138 The opposite effect that originating banks can recover a higher value than servicing firms is claimed in a study with US mortgage funds in Thao Le (2016).
servicer can threaten more aggressively to enforce the loan 139 or the debtor may perceive
such a threat when he is informed about the change of creditor. 140
Why are loan servicers important for NPL market?
Loan servicing firms become a key player when the loan owners do not have the size
and/or capabilities to cope with all the activities loan servicing requires. Loan servicing
helps, also, when tighter financial regulation and increased capital requirements force financial institutions, mainly banks, to reduce their exposure to non-performing loans
(NPLs). Thus, loan servicing provides an essential link between the capital market
investors and ultimate borrowers.
In order to repair their balance sheet, banks can sell part or their entire portfolio of NPLs
to external financial actors (non-bank): investment funds. These funds are interested in the return such portfolio of NPLs could add to their business, but they lack the expertise
on loan servicing that banks have in house. Then, the new owners of the loans need to
hire a loan servicer. This could be either the bank selling the NPLs or an outsourcing
company. To avoid the contamination that past wrongdoing by the banks that originated
the loans could produce, the new loan owners usually choose loan servicing companies without relation with the loan originator, non-bank servicers. Besides, the new loan
owners can increase loan recovery if they focus on loss mitigation to improve recovery
ratios and to reduce time for cashing the loan. However, handling NPLs through loss
mitigation requires discretion, expertise and a huge amount of manpower. 141
Then, expanding NPLs secondary market requires a robust third-party servicing industry
to support investment funds participation. Thus, the growth of non-bank servicer industry in the US was driven by the banks' difficulties in managing their portfolios on NPLs. 142
Non-bank services advantages over in-house banks services come from their
specialization on servicing NPLs and from their ability to reduce costs using
technological innovations. 143
What kind of loan servicers do we have in the EU Member States?
Many of the loan servicers in the EU are part of an investment group either because the
investment company bought the loan servicer or because the loan servicer grew to
139 Banks face stronger reputation effects with respect to new lending business if debtors perceive their enforcement policy against other debtors as unfair.
140 See Experian (2017).
141 Levitin and Twomey (2011).
142 Federal Reserve Board et al., (2016).
143 Federal Reserve Board et al., (2016).
become an investor itself. There are at least 47 companies offering loan servicing in the
EU. Out of the 47, 40 deal with non-performing loans, 35 deal with performing loans and
only 5 monitor a subservicer. Besides, 33 out 47 deal with residential mortgages, 37 with
commercial mortgages and only 7 are in the business of asset finance. At the end of
2016, our best estimate of the volume of loans under management by these loan servicers
in the EU is about EUR 508 billion.
We identified loan servicers in all countries of the EU, but Cyprus and Malta. On the
other hand, UK and Italy are the countries where we countered most loan servicers, 24.
Germany, Spain and Ireland have 15 or 16 loan servicers operating in their countries.
Netherlands, France, Poland, Belgium, or Luxembourg have 5 to 8 third-party loan
servicers. The rest of the countries have a number of loan servicers inferior to 3.
The financial group that serves most countries of the EU is EOS headquartered in
Germany. It is present in 18 out of 28 EU MS. Others groups with present in more than
10 countries are Intrum (recently merged with Lindorff) and Hoist Finance, which are
present in 13 and 11 countries respectively. There are 9 groups that provide loan
servicing in 5 or more EU countries but less than 10. Finally, there are 20 out of the 47
financial groups identified that provide loan servicing just in 1 EU country.
Relative to the stock of outstanding NPLs, the number of loan servicers is small in IT,
EL, FR, PT, CY and possibly ES and AT (see Figure A .5.5 ).
Figure A.5.5: Number of loan servicers and NPLs per Member State (The right-hand chart zooms in on smaller Member States)
Another issue is the location of the headquarters for these groups. Thus, 15 out of 47
groups are from the USA, 9 are headquartered in the UK and the same amount in Italy, 3
from Sweden and from Germany; finally there are 2 groups from Australia, Netherlands
and Spain.
Public information about profitability of these servicers is scarce. The Orbis database
provides information about the profit margin of some of these groups in 2016, though not
of the profitability of their loan servicing activity. Thus, among those groups where we
have been able to calculate their profit margin the average value is 18% per year. The
group with the highest profit margin was Blackstone that owns the loan servicer
Acenden, with a 55% profit margin. Other groups with relative high profit margins were Apollo, KKR, Oaktree or Charter Court with profit margins above 40%. Even though we
have incomplete data, our best approximation for the assets under management of these
groups is well above EUR 1200 billion in 2016.
Figure A.5.6: Profitability of firms offering loan servicing
Source: Company reports (see appendix).
While average Assets under Management of the 16 EU firms in this panel are 1.5 billion
EUR, they are 4.7 for the 12 foreign-owned EU firms. The latest profit data (which may
cover different time periods depending on the reporting date) were on average 13% for
the EU firms in the panel and 22% for the foreign-owned firms. The positive relationship
between size and profitability may be caused by the importance of data procession and
the translation of experiences made with business practices in one Member State to
another one. The pattern is less evident for EU firms, even if some of them are active in
several EU Member States.
Cost structures in loan servicers
The public consultation and self-reported information from market participants suggest
that EU Loan servicers are locally set with very heterogeneous environment that depends
on Member States' national regulations (see Annex 3.2). The benchmark if loan servicers
where homogenously regulated at the EU level could be what has happened in USA.
Thus, Dodd Frank financial reform in USA prompted Banks to reduce their in house
mortgage servicing that were acquired by Non-bank specialty servicers at a pace faster
than their ability to handle the increased volume. Thus, non-banks' market share of USA
loan servicing increased from 15% in 2008 to more than 33% in 2015. 144 The Federal
Reserve Board report (2016) argues that the banks difficulties managing their portfolios
of NPLs along with enforcement actions and settlements on defaulted loans are the key
drives of such a growth by non-banks. Third-party loan servicers were able to benefit
from their specialization on servicing non-performing loans and their ability to harness
technological innovation to reduce costs.
144 Federal Reserve Board (2016)
Such growth generated a considerable operational risk for loan servicers. Thus, subprime servicing industry was essential for development of the secondary market in subprime
mortgage loans but at the same time, the accelerated growth of servicers facilitated the
deterioration of the quality in subprime lending and securitization with a non-forecasted
influence that servicers had on mortgage termination ((McNulty et al, 2017). Then,
McNulty et al (2017) argue that the failure to regulate mortgage loan servicing is one of the causes of the USA bank failure. Servicers need to be held to a high standard. Public
Administration has a role in consumer protection based on asymmetric information and
market power. The borrower does not choose their mortgage servicer and cannot make
changes if they don't like the servicer. (McNulty et al, 2017). In the USA case, it was not
a good solution to split supervisory responsibility on loan servicers over several agencies.
If the responsibility is split is possible that neither agency have incentives and/or
resources to develop major expertise in the topic. (McNulty et al, 2017).
The recent regulatory requirements by USA Congress and regulatory agencies to improve
the quality of servicing have skyrocketed loan servicing costs due to the introduction of
complexity and the lack of a harmonized and unified set of practical standards and
requirements (Housing Finance Policy Center, 2017). According to a panel of experts on loan servicing in the USA, the direct costs of servicing a performing loan per year has
gone from $58 in 2008 to $164 in 2012, $205 in 2013, $170 in 2014 and $181 in 2015.
The main reason for the increases in direct costs is compliance because significant
regulation and legal complexity if a big part of this business (Wheeler, 2015). However,
loan servicing NPLs is a much labour intensity activity which translates into direct costs of servicing these loans that are more than 10 times the costs of servicing performing
loans. Besides, the direct cost of a non performing loan per year has increased four times
to what it cost to service 4 years ago. Its direct cost in 2015 was $2386 while it was $482
in 2008. Mortgage loan servicing is a business where scale increases profitability.
Table A.5.8: Loan servicing costs in the USA
Annual average servicing costs (USD) in USA per 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 loan
Servicing cost per Performing loans (USD) $58.00 $77.00 $90.00 $96.00 $164.00 $205.00 $170.00 $181.00
Additional cost of servicing NPLs $424.0 $626.0 $806.0 $1,266.0 $1,845.0 $2,152.0 $1,779.0 $2,205.0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Source: Federal Reserve Board (2016).
The reason for the differences in servicing costs between performing and non performing
is because the direct costs associated with NPLs include the cost traditionally associated
with performing loans: call center, technology, scrow, cashiering, quality assurance,
investor reporting and executive management, etc, most of them able to automatize; plus the costs specific for non-performing loans: collections, loss mitigation, bankruptcy,
foreclosure and post-sale, unreimbursed foreclosure and real estate owned losses, and
other default specific costs. Then, we observe that servicing NPLs is much more
expensive and the costs associated to those loans have been growing in the USA at a
faster pace that the cost of servicing performing loans (see Table).
Table A.5.9: Changes to loan servicing costs in the USA
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2015-2008
% change in servicing costs performing loans 32.76% 16.88% 6.67% 70.83% 25.00% -17.07% 6.47% 212.07%
% change in servicing costs NPLs 45.85% 27.45% 52.01% 47.50% 17.32% -17.31% 22.42% 395.02%
Source: Mortgage bankers association. Federal Reserve report
The structure of costs in a loan servicer can be divided between: Personnel 65%,
Technology 30% and Ancillary 5%. Then, labour cost management, technology and innovation are essential to improve loan servicers efficiency (Accenture, 2016).
However, such cost structure depends on the number of loans serviced. Thus, The
Federal Reserve Report to the USA Congress shows a U behaviour for a mixture of
performing and non-performing loans. Having servicers that deliver their services to a
large number of loans improves their efficiency but a limit. For instance, if the EU homogenises its rules on third-party loan servicers it could be possible to take advantage
of the economies of scale (Oliver Wyman, 2016).
Table A.5.10: Loan servicing costs and their determinants by firm size in the USA
Number of loans servicing less than 2,500 2,500 to 10,000 10,000 to 50,000 Greater than 50,000
Dollar cost per servicing a $255.00 $171.00 $218.00 $243.00 performing loan in USA, 2015
% in Personnel 37.65% 44.44% 42.20% 47.33%
% in Occupancy and equipment 2.75% 2.34% 4.13% 3.29%
% Technology 0.78% 2.34% 3.67% 4.12%
% Subservicing fees 54.12% 40.94% 32.11% 21.40%
% Other expenses 4.71% 9.94% 17.89% 23.87%
Source: Mortgage bankers association. Federal Reserve report
Then, the servicer needs to get fees that are higher than its costs to be profitable. The
servicing fee is a fixed percentage of the unpaid principal balance (UPB) of the
underlying mortgage. The servicer may receive ancillary fees (late fees and loan
modification fees) and interest earned on principal and interest and taxes and insurance
collected and held by the servicer before distribution to the loan owner.
A PPENDIX : S TATISTICAL OVERVIEW ABOUT THE LOAN SERVICING MARKET
Table A.5.A1 Servicing companies in each EU MS
Country number of loan servicers AuM (EUR
mll)*
AT Austria 3
BE Belgium 5
BG Bulgaria 2
CY Cyprus 0
CZ Czech Republic 2
DE Germany 16 € 44,639.00
DK Denmark 3
EE Estonia 1
EL Greece 10
ES Spain 17 € 12,707.00
FI Finland 1
FR France 7
GB Great Britain 24 € 135,670.00
HR Croatia 2
HU Hungary 3
IE Ireland 14 € 113,300.00
IT Italy 24 € 201,274.00
LT Lithuania 1
LU Luxembourg 6
LV Latvia 1
MT Malta 0
NL Netherlands 11
PL Poland 5
PT Portugal 3 € 370.00
RO Romania 3
SE Sweden 3
SI Slovenia 1
SK Slovakia 2 * Information on Assets under management (AuM) is not available for all countries and for all loan servicers.
Source: Banca IFIS, EMEA service evaluation industry report by S&P and companies' webpages.
Table A5.A2 Specialization of the main loan services in the EU MS
Asset Commercial Residential Primary Special Master finance mortgages mortgages
Apollo non performing loan group X X X X
APS X X X X
Arrow Global Group X X X X X
Axactor X
Bain Capital X X X
Blackstone (Acenden) X X X
Capita Asset Services X X X X X
CBRE loan services X X X
Cerved X X X X
Charter Court (EME) X X X X X
Computershare (HML) X X X
Cortland Capital Market Services X X
Cribis Crecit Management X X X X
Davidson Kempner (PCS) X X X X X
Dea Capital (SPC Credit Management) X X X X
FBS X X X X
Finsolutia X X
Fortress X X X X
Hipoges Iberia X X
Hoist Finance X X X
Intrum X X X
JB Capital Markets (SAM) X X X
K.Red (Non Performing Loans spa) X X X X
KKR X X X X
Link financial outsourcing X X X
Loancos X X X
Lone Star X X X X
Lowell (GFKL Financial Services) X X
Mount Street Loan Solutions (MSLS) X X X
Officine CST X X X X
Pepper Finance Corp. X X X X
Primus (Centaurus Credit Recovery) X X X
Quion X X X X
Securitisation Services X X X X
Situs X X
Solutus Advisors X X
Stater X X
Tages (Credito Fondiario) X X X X X
Target Servicing X X X X X
Varde (Guber) X X X
Vesta X X X X
Wells Fargo CMS X X X
Source: Banca IFIS, EMEA service evaluation industry report by S&P, Orbis database and companies' webpages
Table A5.A.3 Characteristics of the main integrated groups of investors and loan servicers in EU
Company HeadQ. AuM Employees Profit Profit per Avge cost Total assets per EU margin employee employee employee MS
EUR mill 16 % in 16 th EUR 16 th EUR 16 th EUR 16
Computershare (HML) Australia € 32,509.67 17,839 12.34 12 € 201.00 2
Pepper Finance Corp. Australia € 18,600.00 315 18.83 21 € 94.00 4
APS Holding Czech € 5,300.00 9
Loancos Germany na 1
Palmira Germany € 1,200.00 6
EOS Group (Contentia, Credirect)) Germany € 4,565.00 15 18
Target Servicing India € 6,439.56 445 10.01 11 € 67.00 1
Cerved (Fin S. Giaco.; Recus; Tarida) Italy € 12,000.00 160 39.32 88 € 211.00 1
Cribis Crecit Management Italy € 1,000.00 41 14.86 82 € 643.00 1
Dea Capital (SPC Credit Mnt.) Italy € 173.50 186 14.5 68 € 3,768.00 1
FBS Italy € 7,410.00 1
K.Red (Non Performing Loans spa) Italy € 1.00 4 7.78 20 € 224.00 1
Officine CST Italy € 2,000.00 1
Primus (Centaurus Credit Recovery) Italy € 3,600.00 1
Securitisation Services Italy € 20,500.00 1
Tages (Credito Fondiario) Italy € 4,200.00 1
Quion Netherl. € 26.00 365 25.4 45 € 71.00 2
Stater Netherl. € 86.00 826 6.34 13 € 104.00 2
Hipoges Iberia Spain € 5,800.00 1
Finsolutia Spain € 725.00 45 38.99 48 € 124.00 2
Axactor (CS Union) Sweden € 232,000.00 988 -32.01 -14 25 € 324.00 5
Hoist Finance (TRC) Sweden € 1,300.00 1,285 23.95 43 € 1,560.00 11
Intrum (Lindorff) Sweden € 3,352.00 8,000 19.37 71 € 1,055.00 13
Lowell (GFKL Financial Services) UK € 16,000.00 1
JB Capital Markets (Savia Asset M.) UK € 2,700.00 90 0.66 1 € 1,025.00 1
Vesta UK € 500.00 1
Charter Court (Exact Mortgage Ex.) UK € 21,000.00 370 52.42 154 € 13,113.00 1
Solutus Advisors Germany UK € 1,503.55 13 -66.18 € 291.00 2
AnaCap Financial Partners UK € 3,200.00 23 34.64 388 438 € 509.00 2
Capita Asset Services (Capita M. S.) UK € 111,959.34 4 Arrow Global Group (Zenith Service) UK € 41,000.00 1,135 13.3 32 32 € 1,077.00 5
Link financial outsourcing UK € 4,318.68 550 17.42 15 € 104.00 5
Davidson Kempner (Prelios C. S.) USA € 9,680.00 1
Fortress (Italfon., Dobank, UCCMB) USA € 72,400.00 464 18.35 70 € 735.00 1
Cortland Capital Market Services USA na 3 -17.97 -8 € 160.00 1
Wells Fargo Comm Mortgage S. USA € 1,263.74 269,142 36.25 113 € 6,803.00 1
Mount Street Loan Solutions (MSLS) USA € 25,000.00 37 32 171 € 451.00 2
Blackstone (Acenden) USA € 12,051.87 2,120 55.53 1066 € 11,815.00 2
Bain Capital (Heta Asset Resolution) USA € 34,300.00 3
Cargill (Carval Investors) USA € 10,000.00 18 -7.21 -80 € 616.00 3
Lone Star (Hudson Advisors UK) USA € 17,464.85 3
KKR (Sistemia) USA € 40,000.00 1,200 51.11 771 € 30,834.00 4
Apollo Global Mment (Apollo NPL G.) USA € 151,000.00 986 53.85 1021 817 € 5,416.00 4
Varde (Guber) USA € 50,000.00 5
CBRE loan services USA € 117,391.30 75,000 6.74 11 € 136.00 6
Oaktree USA € 86,086.96 900 43.15 6
Situs (Hatfield Philips) USA € 32,000.00 6
Source: Banca IFIS, EMEA service evaluation industry report by S&P, Orbis database and companies' webpages
A NNEX 6: T HE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK OF NPL TRANSFERS AND LOAN SERVICERS
-
1.A STOCKTAKE OF R ULES IN THE EU M EMBER S TATES : R ESULTS OF THE QUESTIONNAIRE TO M EMBER S TATES
Within the context of efforts to improve the functioning of secondary markets for distressed debt and to facilitate the disposal of non-performing loans (NPLs) by banks,
the Commission sent a fact-finding questionnaire to Member States in April 2017 in
order to gather information on servicing of loans by third parties and transfer of NPLs.
Replies to the fact-finding questionnaire have been received from 25 Member States
(MS). This text summarises the replies and represents a stock take of rules in place.
1.1 Executive summary
Most Member States lack legal definitions of loan servicing activities and concerns
regarding consumer protection affect differently the activities that may be considered
loan servicing. In many cases, a set of core activities performed by the creditor are
defined by law and outsourcing them is generally allowed only under strict conditions such as an authorization by the competent authority or that the creditor remains, to some
degree, responsible for the activity. Therefore, the particular activities that can be
outsourced differ across countries.
In the large majority of Member States, there are no specific requirements for loan
servicers when they enter the market, although in order to manage the loan, some countries require either a full or restricted banking license or compliance with some fit
and proper criteria. Non-EU loan servicers are permitted in almost all Member States and
they do not face additional requirements.
Member States have in general a favourable legal environment for NPL transfer and the
entry of specialised investors. First, there is at least one type of contract in each Member
State that can allow the transfer of loans without the debtor's consent. When consent is required, it is usually possible to provide it in abstract in the loan documentation and
most loan contracts seem to make use of this possibility. Member States have indicated
neither a separate consent for the transfer of the collateral, nor additional obstacles to
transfer a loan when it is subject to enforcement actions. 145 The transfer of NPLs to nonfinancial
institutions is also allowed in all MS, except one. Lastly, notification to the debtor is required in ten MS, and it is a standard practice even in those countries where it
is not mandatory.
The Member States' responses to the questionnaire do not reveal severe additional
regulatory requirements to the transfer of loans. Some types of loans, namely consumer
145 In-court and out-of-court foreclosure proceedings.
credit or loans under a certain value face some stricter requirements on the buyer due to consumer protection provisions. In addition, the buyer is required in some cases to get a
banking license. The transferor does not encounter further regulatory barriers either,
although some Member States require an authorisation in case of significantly large
transactions due to competition law or financial stability concerns. The questionnaire has
not revealed that investment funds face any restrictions when they acquire NPLs beyond some general rules to protect retail investors.
Responses suggest that bank secrecy and data protection can be a barrier to share data for
due diligence, however the legal framework of most Member States generally contains an
exemption that allows the bank to disclose data which are necessary and proportionate
for selling the loan. Moreover, where the debtor gives consent, which seems to be a standard practice, banks have more leeway to disclose personal information.
These results are consistent with the ECB Stocktake of national supervisory practices and
legal frameworks related to NPLs (See Appendix). It should be noted however, that they
reflect authorities views and our reading of what the rules intend. Market participants'
perception of regulatory entry barriers and their effectiveness may differ and therefore it
is warranted to cross check the conclusions with the replies from the currently running public consultation.
1.2 Background
Within the context of efforts to improve the functioning of secondary markets for
distressed debt and to facilitate the disposal of non-performing loans (NPLs) by banks, the Commission sent a fact-finding questionnaire to Member States on 7 April in order to
gather information on their respective relevant national legal provisions.
The aim was in particular to obtain information on:
-
1.servicing of loans by third parties and non-bank loan investors, and
-
2.transfer of loans, including non-performing loans, to bank and non-bank entities and
these entities' subsequent ownership and management of these assets.
Within the context of the discussions in the FSC Subgroup on NPLs it was deemed
necessary to investigate whether legal provisions might restrict the above mentioned
activities in some Member States. Such restrictions may include rules for the transfer of
credit contracts or restrictions applicable to purchasers of NPLs. In some cases, the transfer of a loan might only be possible with the debtor's consent. Likewise, access to
information concerning the loan and/or the borrower may be restricted, for example due
to considerations of data protection. Limitations can also apply to potential buyers by
requiring a banking licence or by imposing other restrictions. The availability of NPL
servicing also plays a role in the development of secondary markets for distressed assets.
National rules, including licencing rules, governing the provision of third-party loan
servicing, currently vary between Member States.
1.3. Assessment of answers to the questionnaire
1.3.1 L OAN SERVICING ACTIVITIES
1.3.1.1 Legal definitions of loan servicing activities
In most Member States, there are no formal legal definitions of 'servicing', 'managing'
and/or 'debt collection' of loans, neither of other ancillary activities undertaken by banks after the granting of the loan. Loan servicing activities primarily fall under the freedom
of contract.
Some Member States do put forward certain definitions/descriptions. EE establishes
minimum requirements for loan servicing, which involves activities of granting loans,
analysing, monitoring and evaluation. IE defines “credit servicing” as “managing and administering the credit agreement". The EL law 146 stipulates the indicative content of
the management /servicing activities for NPL servicing companies as the legal and
accounting monitoring, collecting, conducting negotiations with debtors. In LV, debt
recovery activities fall under dedicated definitions and are regulated. 147 In the UK, a distinction is made between regulated mortgages (‘mortgage administration’ 148 ) and
consumer credit with definition for 'debt collecting' and 'debt administration'.
1.3.1.2 Potential requirements on the outsourcing creditor 149
In almost all Member States, there are no explicit prerequisites that a creditor has to
satisfy before outsourcing certain servicing functions. As a general rule, it is not permitted to outsource core activities, which may be subject to a banking license and
regulatory supervision, albeit these core activities differ depending on the Member State.
If a subset of servicing functions is to be outsourced, there are general provisions on
outsourcing applicable in the majority of Member States. For instance, the creditor is
expected to assess whether the firm to which it outsources fulfils fit-and-proper criteria
and compliance with the most relevant rules applicable to them (anti-money laundering, customer protection regulations, etc.). The creditor remains liable for any breaches by the
provider of outsourced services of any regulatory requirements in relation to the
servicing of the loans (e.g. in IE, DK, NL). Furthermore, there are often minimum
requirements in terms of risk management (e.g. in DE, IE, EE).
146 Law 4354/2015.
147 “Law n Extrajudicial Recovery of Debt” regulates the rights and duties of a creditor and a provider of debt recovery services in the field of debt recovery.
148 The related law essentially covers notifying and collecting the amounts due and taking necessary steps to ensure payment of these
149 Either the originator or an investor who have acquired the credit claim after inception
In EL, if the outsourcing creditor is not a supervised bank of financial institution, it can outsource only to a servicing company that is properly licensed and supervised by the
Bank of Greece.
If outsourcing is deemed to affect core functions or services, it is not allowed or tied to
strict requirements. For instance in DE, loan monitoring can only be subject to
outsourcing if concrete criteria are defined for such activities; however credit decisions cannot be outsourced. In ES and MT, outsourcing of core activities requires authorisation
by the competent authority. Some Member States do not allow to outsource refinancing,
which is considered part of a credit/lending decision (e.g. in DE) or they require strict
conditions to the outsourced institution (e.g. in RO).
As regards undertaking formal enforcement actions, in the large majority of Member States the creditor cannot outsource. Investor-linked servicers are not permitted to
undertake formal enforcement actions on the creditor’s behalf. In EL, however, loan
servicers are entitled to all necessary legal remedies and can proceed to any other judicial
action for the collection of the debts under their management. 150
1.3.1.3 Potential requirements on the loan servicer
In the large majority of Member States, loan servicers are not legally required to comply
with specific requirements. Loan servicers are in the vast majority of Member States
neither required to obtain a full (except for SK, RO and NL in some cases) 151 nor a
restricted banking license (except for HU and FR). In almost all cases, servicers do need
to comply with certain fit-and-proper requirements. In IE and EL, servicers are required to comply with specific requirements and only entities that have an appropriate licence
can conduct credit servicing. In LV, a provider of debt recovery services requires a
special license. In the UK, the servicer of mortgage loans and consumer credit is required
to meet some fit-and-proper criteria. 152 EL explicitly requires loan servicers to follow
consumer protection including special care for the socially vulnerable groups.
Non-EU loan servicers are permitted in almost all Member States, except EL and they do
not face additional requirements. In EL, non-EU loan servicers are not permitted and
non-Greek EU loan servicers must act through a branch. Nonetheless, in AT, in case of
pure outsourcing, stricter requirements can apply especially with regard to data
150 Servicing companies will appear as non-beneficiary (third) parties in court proceedings and any relevant judgement shall be binding upon the lenders of the relevant loans.
151 Servicing of a loan is considered as a banking activity. In fact, the bank that transferred the loan to a third-party is allowed to continue performing the servicing of the claim, if its banking license allows for the management of claims on behalf of clients, including advisory services. RO only regarding refinancing since it is considered lending activity.
152 I.e. certain “fit and proper” criteria, specific form of incorporation, location of headquarters or incorporation, the ability to meet operational requirements and the ability to meet specific compliance and audit requirements.
protection issues, as the legal situation outside the EU is less harmonized. Whereas there are no explicit restrictions for non-EU loan servicers in SE, the supervision of the data
protection authority may create a practical obstacle for some non-EU firms.
When a licensing/permit requirement exists on the part of the servicer, the exact criterion
triggering the related procedure differs from one Member State to another. In IE, an
authorisation is required when a firm is servicing loans on behalf of an unregulated entity. In EL licensing requirements differ between “simple” servicing companies and
those that provide refinancing. In AT, factoring requires a licence, because the purchase
and the acceptance of the risk associated with such receivables are decisive. In HU, the
trigger is when a commercial activity is involved.
In Member States where third-party servicers need to go through a licensing process, the timeline differs from one country to another: 1 month in LV, 2 months in EL, ca. 3
months in AT, 5 to 6 months in HU. The UK has a statutory deadline of 12 months for
deciding on submitted applications for regulatory permission. In IE, it is not possible to
define timelines as yet, as the country's new authorisation regime was introduced only in
July 2015.
Authorities that have the ability to grant licences to third-party servicers are the Member
State's Central Bank (CY, HU, IE, EL), the Consumer Rights Protection Centre in the
case of LV, the Financial Market Authority in AT, and the Financial Conduct Authority
in the UK. In SE, the data protection authority also has a role.
The type of documentation required for any licensing application can be very diverse.
This can entail generic information disclosure requirements (e.g. in CY, IE, LV, UK,
HU), such as a description of the services, details of the service provider, the business
plan, compliance plan, internal audit plan, specific conditions of the contract. EL
prescribes a minimum capital paid in (EUR 100.000 for simple servicers and EUR 4.5
million for those that provide refinancing). On top of such general information, more
details can be required about, for example, the amount of initial capital freely available (AT), or qualifying shareholder information (AT, IE). HU requires financial institutions
applying for authorization to enclose (in addition to more general information): the
proposed area of operations, a minimum amount of the initial capital for credit
institutions. Furthermore, if the applicant is established abroad, a number of extra
requirements are in place, e.g. a statement on having a main office in Hungary from which governance of the financial institution takes place.
1.3.2 Transfer of Loans
1.3.2.1 Civil law provisions on the transfer of loans
In principle, all Member States have at least one type of contract (either transfer of the
credit rights or transfer of the loan contract) that allows the transfer of loan without the debtor's consent. Under the freedom of contract, debtor's consent can be either stipulated
in the contract or exempted when it is required. When consent is required, it can be
provided in standard forms and both in abstract at the time of the loan and at the time of
the transfer (LT holds that consent in abstract would be legally problematic). Those Member States that differentiate between the transfer of the credit rights (or receivables) and the more common transfer of the loan (or all the rights and obligations of the
contract) require the debtor's consent for the latter (ES, PT, FR, IE, SI, AT, DE). As a
rule, Member States would provide that the debtor shall enjoy the same legal position
vis-à-vis the transferee of the loan than against the transferor. The only countries where
debtor's consent is generally required by operation of law are SK and BE. Nonetheless, in SK, if the debtor has been more than 90 days in arrears (NPLs), consent is not required.
In BE, if both assignor and assignee are financial institutions that transfer big portfolios
of loans, debtor's consent will be overridden by an authorization from the competent
authority. BG prohibits the transfer of consumer's credit loans unless already envisaged
in the contract.
The collateral is generally transferred with the loan, thus it does not require a separate
consent (SI requires consent when the collateral is in transferor's possession). There are
no problems to transfer the loan when it is subject to enforcement actions (Only UK
requires the court's approval). The transfer of NPLs to non-financial institutions is
allowed in nearly all MS with the sole exception of CY that only permits to sell the loans to banks and financial institutions as eligible buyers).
The validity of the transfer of the loan seems to require notification in PT, CZ (when it is
pledged), EE, BG, HU, SK, CY, FI, HR, IE (2 months in advance for loans that affect
individuals and SMEs) and EL (the main terms must be registered with the competent
Pledge Registry and following such registration, the borrower and, if applicable, any
guarantor should be notified). In the rest of countries, notification is not mandatory, albeit the transfer of the loan does not produce effects against the debtor without it. The
consequence would be that either the payment to the first creditor would discharge the
borrower's debt or the transferees could not enforce their rights against the debtor.
Therefore, debtor's notification is standard practice even in those MS where notification
is not mandatory.
In general, the transfer of the collateral rights does not require a specific form.
Nonetheless, if the collateral is registered because it is pledged or it is a mortgage loan,
the transfer of the collateral in some MS requires access to the register as well (PT, IE,
BG, DK). Other MS require the same specific form as the loan contract (SI, LV, LT). In
some MS, there are ways to transfer the loan without a specific form, but the notarial certification and registration is either a general practice or it is required to have access
and benefit from the previous registration (ES, FR, DE, CZ, BE, AT). Some MS declared
that their laws do not require any specific form (UK, FI, SK, EE). In HU, there is not a
specific form, unless the loan portfolio is above HUF 1bn.
1.3.2.2 Potential regulatory requirements and restrictions on the transferee/buyer
Although some countries require banking licenses when the loans are performing (FR,
PT, SK, LT), NPLs are exempted. Nine Member States (HR, ES, FI, IE, DK, SK, PT,
LT, UK) hold that the buyer of NPLs does not encounter additional regulatory
constraints. Some additional specific requirements can be triggered depending on the type of loans (consumer credit or loans under a certain threshold) due to consumer protection provisions (SI, BE, SK, NL) or the nature of the activity (credit business or
factoring) (DE, AT). Three Member States (BG, RO, EL) require fit and proper criteria,
including a specific form of incorporation and the location of either head offices or a
branch in the country. EL requires investors to sign a loan management agreement with a
servicing company properly licensed and supervised by the Bank of Greece (see above).
HU requires a restricted banking license and CY a full banking license. Thus potential
licensing/permit requirement may be required because of the buyer's commercial activity
in five Member States (DE, AT, EE, SK, BE). The type of loan could also trigger some
specific requirements (SI, BE, SK, BG).
Non-EU institutions face the same requirements as EU-domiciled investors in the
majority of MS. EL requires foreign firms to operate in the country through a local branch and neither being from a tax haven nor from a non-cooperating country. 153 Other
exceptions are AT, HU, and BE (in case of companies domiciled in a tax haven), but they
did not give further details in their reply.
1.3.2.3 Potential regulatory requirements on the transferor
Only three MS (BE, HR, LV) require authorisation on the transferor by the supervisor
authority. Nonetheless, other countries require authorisation under some conditions (HU,
DK, AT, LT) such as the volume of the deal (HU), competition law concerns (AT, LT) or both parties are financial institutions (DK). Getting approval from the supervisor, when
required, lasts between one (LV) and six months (AT). Although Member States are not
very concise about the requirements that trigger the authorisation, it is possible to
identify transferees' book and market value (HU) and financial stability risks (HU and
BE).
It is possible to identify other additional regulatory constraints on the transferor. First, IE
requires a notification to the debtor two months in advance for some type of loans
(natural persons and SMEs) due to provisions on consumer protection. Secondly, CY
permits both the debtor and the guarantor to submit a proposal to purchase the loan 45
days after the notification. A third factor is data protection and bank secrecy as mentioned below.
153 according to Greek tax law 4172/2013.
1.3.2.4. Role of investment funds to buy loans 154
In most Member States, loans are eligible assets for alternative investment funds (in the
meaning of AIFMD). In BG national investment funds cannot invest in NPLs, although
AIF under the threshold of the AIFMD have no restrictions. In HU, loans are only
eligible forms of investments if they are in the forms of derivative instruments and only UCITS are entitled to buy loan-based derivatives. There are special funds in SE that market shares to retail investors, which are not allowed to invest in loans. 155
Both open-ended and closed-ended funds are authorised to buy loans with the exceptions
of BE and FI where only closed-ended funds are entitled. In ES, closed-ended funds can
invest in participative loans only under some conditions and up to certain thresholds. The
particular legal forms of the funds are quite different in every Member State and they adapt to the different legal traditions.
It is common that only institutional/professional investors are permitted to invest in loanparticipating
funds. However some Member States entitle non-professional investors
when they invest an amount above a certain threshold (€20.000 in LV, €100.000 in ES
and CZK 1 million in CZ). Some Member States (ES, DK, DE) also extend this investment option to non-professional investors under strict conditions such as signature
of risk knowledge or investment limits.
Managers of large alternative investment funds (in excess of AIFMD requirements) do
not encounter specific minimum capital or other additional regulatory constraints, such as
governance requirements, legal structures or restrictions to the outsourcing to third-party servicers in most Member States. However, PT imposes some fit and proper criteria on
managers and it requires some legal corporate structure to the funds such as a
management body, a supervisory body and an external auditor. Managers and funds in
ES and DE shall comply with some governance requirements and investor protection
regulations if they want to become entities supervised by the competent authority and enjoy tax advantages. In all Member States, the relevant investment funds are supervised
by either the financial supervisory authorities or Central Banks.
Lastly, although there are some differences across the EU, the timeline for the
authorisation or registration process of the relevant investment funds lasts between 20
working days and 6 months depending on the type of fund. In addition, most Member
States did not report any specific tax provisions in place which may restrict and/or
154 A number of Member States (MT, UK, SK) did not submit any answer to the questions related to the role of investment funds to buy loans.
155 These are AIF with permission from the Swedish FSA under the national regime to market shares to retail investors.
disincentive the transfer/sale of loans as long as funds engage in pure investment activities (in contrast to commercial activities).
1.3.3 Data protection and bank secrecy provisions
Another common pattern in Member States' replies is that the bank remains responsible
vis-à-vis the client for the treatment of the data when it outsources some activities to a
servicer. The Member States which are more specific on this hold that the creditor, in most cases the originating bank, has to sign an agreement with the servicer that regulates
the use of personal data. The servicer shall not use the personal data for other purposes
than those established in such agreement. On the other hand, if the bank transfers the loan
and deletes all personal data, it is not responsible vis-à-vis the client anymore (ES, FR,
IE, AT, HU, FI, BE). Some MS hold that the bank retains responsibility when it transfers the loan to entities which are not subject to bank secrecy (CZ, MT SK and LT). Three
MS (PT, SI and EE) only mention that the transferor retains responsibility vis-à-vis the
client but they do not specify how.
Bank secrecy provisions generally contain an exemption that allows the bank to disclose
data which are necessary and proportionate for selling the loan. In the case that the debtor gave consent, which seems to be a general practice, the bank would have more leeway to
disclose personal data. This exception is explicit in HR and HU for the selling of
receivables. Other Member States hold that the disclosure of debtor's protected
information can in certain cases be considered as a legitimate interest of the transferor,
which would be an exemption to bank secrecy provisions according to their national law (ES, FR, IE, RO, SI, DK, CY, FI, BE, MT, CZ). The strictest regimes appear to be in BG
and AT where the transfer of confidential data is only allowed under the debtor's consent
or an authority's decision.
It seems to be standard practice in most of MS that the seller describes the loan without
disclosing confidential and personal data in the initial transaction phase and may only disseminate such information in a second stage or when the contract has been concluded.
Those who have access to confidential information must keep it confidential.
-
2.OBSTACLES FLAGGED IN THE PUBLIC CONSULTATION
The public consultation preceding this impact assessment asked stakeholders to identify obstacles to the development of secondary markets and to communicate their assessment of the obstacles' importance to marekt development. This annex provides an overview of the main obstacles emerging from the consultation responses. Following are the main obstacles that came out of the consultation, organized around four main pillars: data quality and availability; legal system & collateral enforcement; costs of entry & asset transfers; and recovery expectations & disposal losses.
Table A6.1. Obstacles to the development of secondary market for NPLs
-
A.Data quality & B. Legal system & C. Costs of entry & D. Recovery availability collateral asset transfers expectations & enforcement disposal losses
Banking secrecy Ability to obtain stay Licensing Collateral valuation on enforcement requirements for gap
investors & services Consumer privacy Right to settle at Cross-border Regulatory approach
transfer price authorizations (nonon provisioning EU)
Standardization of data Efficiency of out-of Taxes & other costs Tax disincentives on court mechanism due to transfers provisioning
Cross-border Economic conditions Impact on disposal differences in losses on regulatory collateral enforcement capital
Cross-border Social & political differences in dunning resistence to collateral process enforcement
Judicial & operational capacity
Source: EC Consultation Responses
2.1 Data quality & availability
The unavailability of high quality data has been picked as the main obstacle to the development of secondary NPL markets by most respondents. The inability of a prospective buyer to discern the quality of the assets, which is intrinsically known to the
seller, leads to an outcome where only the low quality assets, or "lemons", are traded. 156
These information asymmetries lower bid prices, obstruct the price discovery process, and may even impede altogether the development of a secondary market. To overcome these challenges, prospective investors typically conduct a detailed review of the relevant
156 See G. Akerlof (1970) “The market for “lemons”: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol 84, No. 3, pp 488-500.
portfolio prior to making an offer for the for-sale portfolio. Ideally, the analysis should be similar to the credit risk and recovery assessments made by the banks originating the loans, involving the assessment of the expected future cash flows, collateral realization and costs related to servicing, selling, or enforcing the contract. Such an analysis is usually hampered when investors lack access to data on payment histories, recovery rates, or collateral valuations on comparable exposures.
Banking secrecy and consumer privacy issues are identified as the main reason for the limited flow of information to buyers. As highlighted by one respondent, the need to overcome the inherent information asymmetries has to be balanced with privacy
concerns. In many jurisdictions 157 , banking secrecy rules prevent banks or other entities
managing credit exposures to disclose client-specific information to third-parties. This effectively prevents the transfer of loan-specific data prior to a sale, unless valid client consent is available, even when the loan is non-performing. The transfer of the portfolio to another entity, such as securitization special purpose vehicles (SSPVs) or external servicers, to conduct the pre-sale due diligence on behalf of the investors to circumvent these rules against divulging client-specific information is deemed too costly, further adding to the bid-ask spread.
The uniformity of the data on the NPLs and the underlying collateral are also identified as an obstacle undermining general data quality. In some countries, banks cannot transfer data outside the country, inhibit cross-border entry. Similarly, the nonuniform nature of loan-level data on NPLs and legal documentations limit the gains from economies of scale that would be available to international players. Several participants welcome the renewed focus on achieving data uniformity at the EU level, but point at areas that have not received adequate attention. 158 For example, a number of respondents identify the lack of comparable, reliable and granular information on real estate market transactions as a major shortfall, rendering benchmark comparisons difficult.
2.2 Legal system & collateral enforcement
Most respondents identified lengthy and onerous legal procedures for enforcing loans as a key obstacle to the development of NPL secondary markets. Lengthy and costly enforcement procedures introduce legal uncertainty and lower the net present value of the expected recovery proceeds, thereby driving up the bid-ask spread. Several respondents highlighted that a major issue was the ability of borrowers to oppose and
157 According to evidence from the consultation responses, banking secrecy rules prohibit the transfer of information prior to a sale of loans in Austria, Cyprus, Denmark, France, and Portugal. In Czech Republic, Germany, Hungary, and Poland banking secrecy rules do not apply for nonperforming loans.
158 More recently, in its July 2017 action plan to tackle non-performing loans in Europe, the European Council has invited the EBA, ECB, and the European Commission to propose by end 2017 initiatives to strengthen the data infrastructure with uniform and standardised data for NPLs and consider the setting-up of NPL transaction platforms. In line with this call, EBA has recently developed NPL templates to take into account different data needs of potential NPL investors. ECB has also worked on a broader loan-level data reporting project, which was adopted by the ECB Governing Council in May 2016, to collect granular loan-level data (AnaCredit) for all loans to legal entities and establish a shared database for the European System of Central Banks (ESCB) starting with September 2018.
obtain stay on legal enforcement actions. 159 Lengthy enforcement procedures also increase the risk that the collateral may deteriorate in value, particularly for loans backed by industrial plants or industrial warehouses. Borrowers whose loans were sold have the right to settle their loans at the price of assignment, without distinguishing whether the loan is performing or non-performing. 160 In addition to unlocking NPL sales, addressing these issues can also lower strategic defaults and incentivize borrowers to engage voluntarily with creditors.
The efficiency of out-of-court procedures is also partly dependent on the ability of creditors to enforce the collateral. If creditors can foreclose the collateral with relative speed and reasonable costs, this can also incentivize borrowers to lower negotiate with the creditor voluntarily, as in the case of out-of-court procedures. In many countries, the out-of-court enforcements or sales, much like their legal counterparts, involve lengthy
notification periods. More importantly, in many member states 161 debtors have the ability
to stall the process through legal action, which was identified as a main reason lowering the use of out-of-court sales in Spain. One respondent highlighted that out-of-court financial collateral agreements are made difficult as the borrowers have the ability to request, and re-request) valuations by third parties.
Several respondents also noted that there are severe cross-border differences in the legal procedures and their application. In particular, differences over the application of legal foreclosures, insolvency procedures, consumer protection laws, as well as out-ofcourt procedures constrain the gains from economies of scale for larger international investors. National differences and legal impediments over the dunning process (i.e. methodical communication with borrowers to ensure the collection of accounts receivable) are also reported. The respondents also note that there are legal impediments to access of the creditors to contact data of the debtors for non-creditors. As a whole, these procedural differences make it difficult for cross-border investors and services to automate and standardize the maintenance of NPLs.
The improvement of judicial and operational capacity could help improve recovery expectations in certain regions. Small claims courts do not exist in some member states, which undermines efficiency of the legal procedures for credit recovery and lengthening the collection term and cost. The length of bankruptcy proceedings in certain member states 162 vary substantially depending on the assigned court, which are perceived
159 The issue of debtor protection in the case of NPLs was identified as a major impediment to the further development of NPL secondary sales in Italy. In France, borrowers can insert terms to limit the transferability of their debt at the time of origination. In Cyprus and Greece, transfer of loans may require the explicit consent of the borrower, even in the case of non-performing loans. In many jurisdictions, including most notably France, Cyprus, Ireland, Italy, and Spain, borrowers have the ability to launch appeals, stays, or suspended evictions, in the event of any legal dispute.
160 Although, these practices aim to protect borrowers and avoid litigious claims in the case of sale of performing loans, they severely undermine investor interest in the case of non-performing loans, effectively limiting any potential benefits. In Spain, such provisions appear to exist in Navarra and Cataluña (for residential properties), although their legality has been challenged.
161 According to evidence form the consultation responses pledgees have the ability to stall collateral repossessions in Italy and various Spanish regions.
162 Respondents to the consultation identified Ireland, Italy and Portugal as countries where the length of bankruptcy proceedings varies substantially.
to be due to differences in the capacity of those courts in dealing with NPL resolutions.
In addition, property appraisals conducted in the context of secured NPL securitisations are characterised by high levels of uncertainty. Valuation uncertainty is driven partly by the illiquid nature of the assets securing the loans. This uncertainty is exacerbated by lengthy recovery procedures.
2.3 Costs of entry & asset transfers
Specific entry barriers and the inability of certain investors to purchase assets have also been identified as important obstacles to the development of secondary markets. To that extent, certain jurisdictions allow a sale of NPLs only if the investors are financial entities or even banks, which inhibit entry from a wider spectrum of investors. 163 NPL transfers may also be subject to specific authorization requirements and approvals of local authorities in the case where foreign entities are involved, which increased transaction costs. These restrictions are at times more poignant for foreign, in particular non-EU, investors. 164 As noted above, in some jurisdictions the consent of the debtor may also be sought prior to the transfer of assets. These restrictions are particularly present for the transfer of retail NPLs. The presence of entry barriers and transfer restrictions may impede investor interest and, at best, focus investors' interest in sufficiently large markets where they may reap net benefits from obtaining the required licenses and authorization.
In addition to licensing and authorization requirements, taxes on loan transfers have been identified as a second impediment to the development of the secondary NPL markets. There are a number of tax contingencies that may arise from the transfer of loans. First, losses on asset disposals may not be tax deductible for the originating bank and may give rise to taxable income for debtors. 165 Second, in some countries asset transfers may give rise to withholding taxes on interest income, stamp duties, or other
administrative costs, such as notarial costs and collateral registration fees. 166
A number of respondents also highlight that local social, political and economic conditions may also be important determinants of entry decisions for investors. The underlying economic conditions are clearly an important factor for the expected value of the NPLs. A lower unemployment rate and higher growth rate have a positive impact on
163 In certain jurisdictions, only entities holding banking licenses are allowed to buy NPLs, including Cyprus, Slovenia (for consumer loans), and Germany (where further loan drawings may be involved). In others, like Spain (for mortgage loans) and Hungary, only financial entities are allowed to buy NPLs. In Italy, investors are able to invest in NPL portfolios only through a local SPV supervised by the national authority. In Romania, investors have to be authorized by the domestic Consumer Protection Authority.
164 In Germany, non-EU investors investing in NPL are required to establish a local German servicing enterprise. One respondent complained that non-EU entities may face substantial difficulty in Hungary to obtain local licenses and authorizations for managing NPLs, including banking license and tax exemptions.
165 In Poland, disposal losses are tax deductible only if the relevant NPLs were enforced (i.e. foreclosures) or if debtor was declared insolvent.
166 In Spain, stamp duties (Actos Jurídicos Documentados) and other administrative costs (i.e. notary and registry fees) are seen by several respondents as the main obstacle to the development of secondary market transactions.
cure rates, effectively increasing the expected returns for investors. Political conditions can be determinant in two distinct ways. First, much like macro-economic conditions, political stability can help ensure high future returns. Second, and perhaps more importantly, collateral enforcement may be made difficult due to political and social atmosphere. This is especially the case in countries enforcing loan contracts are seen as putting people out of their homes, i.e. where retail mortgage NPLs are concerned, and where there is a public perception of unfair practices or financial misconduct by banks. To that extent, certain investors may be concerned with reputational risks arising from the use of recovery procedures, including foreclosures or more intrusive collection practices. Conversely, originating banks may also perceive NPL disposal harmful on their existing relationships with their customers. 167
The cost and availability of loan servicers has been identified amongst the entry obstacles most participants. Third-party services represent an alternative for buyers of NPLs to manage the loans and client relations. Having a third-party servicer also allows the investors to sell the assets to other investors in the future, effectively providing them an outside option. However, in some jurisdictions the servicers have to be licensed and
possibly supervised, much like the investors. 168 As another key complaint, several
respondents noted that these requirements, apart from being onerous, differed substantially, undermining the economies of scale advantages that many international services rely on. Despite these concerns, however, several respondents note that debt servicers are becoming more common-place across the EU, especially over the last two years, embracing new asset classes.
2.4 Recovery expectations and disposal losses
Higher recovery expectations of the originating bank is seen by several respondents as the main cause of a high ask price in the context of NPL sales. It is quite common that buyer and sellers have different valuations of the underlying assets, especially in the case of NPLs where data quality and availability issues may exist (see above). However, valuation gaps may exist even in the absence of those issues. For example, the buyers and the sellers may have different discount rates to discount the future cash flows, effectively widening the bid-ask spread especially in countries where recoveries take substantial amount of time. As another example, investors and originating lenders may have different stances in assessing recoveries. Investors often aim to conduct a detailed and "dispassionate assessment" of the expected recovery, relying exclusively on recent collateral valuations, payment histories of lenders, and other forms of verifiable data on expected future cash flows. Originating lenders, on the other hand, may conduct a more subjective assessment, possibly due to the presence of "endowment biases", blending in their current financial positions (i.e. the ability to absorb losses) or any past/future commercial relationship with the borrower.
167 One respondent noted that there is a general negative public conception of and campaigns against servicers and debt collection agencies (the DCAs), especially in some central Eastern European countries.
168 According to consultation responses, third-party servicers have to have specific licenses in Germany, Greece, Slovakia, and supervised in Romania.
Losses form NPL sales were also seen as a key obstacle to the development of NPL markets. Disposals can lead to losses due to several reasons. First, and foremost, disposing assets that are not adequately provisioned leads to financial losses, especially when market conditions are depressed. Apart from the subjective assessments mentioned above, under-provisioning may also arise due to regulatory or fiscal disincentives (i.e. non-deductibility of provisioning losses). Forbearance rules may also allow banks to graduate NPLs to performing status, even on a temporary basis, circumventing the need to provision more. As a second manner in which disposals may generate losses, banks using advanced internal ratings-based (A-IRB) models may suffer from higher capital
requirements in the future as the losses appear in their historical data sheets. 169 Lastly,
heightened preference for an accelerated NPL reduction may flood the market with similar types of assets and lead to fire sales.
Appendix to Annex 6
6.A.1 IMF and ECB/SSM Surveys about the legal framework of NPL markets in the EU
A.1 IMF survey of country authorities and banks 2015
In 2015, the IMF (2015a, b) conducted a survey among 19 country authorities as well as 10 banks operating in these countries about institutional obstacles related to (1) the supervisory framework, (2) the legal system, (3) distressed debt markets, (4) informational shortcomings, and (5) the tax regime. At the request of country authorities, the individual country replies were not revealed, i.e. the table below does not display
which country gave which rating. 170 While the responses reveal a considerable variation,
the concerns were on average somewhat more severe with respect to the legal framework and distressed debt market than for other issues addressed by the NPL Action Plan. While the questions on the legal framework were related to insolvency procedures and
enforcement of NPLs 171 , the issues identified with market development related to:
-
(1)incomplete credit information on borrowers;
-
(2)lack of licensing and regulatory regimes to enable nonbanks to own and manage NPLs;
-
(3)overvalued collateral and lack of liquid real estate markets;
169 These concerns were raised in particular in the context of Italian and Romanian banking systems.
170 The survey was completed by 10 banking groups (Alpha Bank, Intesa, NBG, Piraeus, Pro Credit, Raiffeisen, Societe Generale, Unicredit, Eurobank, and Erste Group) and 19 countries, of which 9 euro-area Members States (Cyprus, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Portugal, Slovenia, and Spain), 3 non-euro area Member States (Croatia, Hungary, Romania) and 7 non-EU countries (Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina (from two separate jurisdictions), Iceland Macedonia, Montenegro, San Marino, and Serbia).
171 IMF (2015a), technical background paper reports a high correlation of the results of the survey with respect to legal obstacles and the World Bank Doing Business indicators on the insolvency frameworks and contract enforcement.
-
(4)low recovery values, partly related to lengthy court procedures; and
-
(5)inadequate provisioning of NPLs.
Overall, the IMF survey suggests that potential buyers of NPL face relatively few explicit restrictions. Most countries allow that third-party (including foreign) banks, as well as institutional investors buy NPLs from local banks. The survey responses also document that obstacles to market entry existed in some Member States still in 2015 (see Figure 6), though some conditions have changed in a few Member States since then, most obviously with respect to the activity of loan servicing firms.
Table A6.A1 IMF assessment of determinants of NPLs in EU Member States
Table A6.A2 IMF assessment of determinants of NPL markets in EU Member States
6.A.2 ECB/SSM Stocktake 2017
The ECB Banking supervision's (SSM) "Stocktake of national supervisory practices and legal
frameworks related to NPLs" collected data from national competent authorities of the 19 euro area MS in December 2016. The survey indicates that the regulatory framework in all
participating countries allows banks to outsource NPL loan servicing activities, although this
practice remains uncommon in many Member States. The Stocktake also shows that legal and
regulatory frameworks present a favourable environment for NPL transfer and the entry of
specialised investors into the local market. The few countries that had legal impediments, such as
portfolio transfer restrictions on non-banking institutions or barriers to the entry of foreign investors, have amended their regulatory frameworks.
Table A6.A3 SSM assessment of loan servicing rules in euro area Member States
Table A6.A4 SSM assessment of rules applying to the Sale of loan portfolios in euro area Member States
6.A.3. Authorisation rules for Loan servicers and NPL purchasers in the EU Member States
Information provided by Member States in summer 2017 unless otherwise indicated
Loan servicers NPL purchasers BE There is no direct supervision by the Belgian The answer depends on the nature of the acquired
prudential supervisor towards the servicer. The loans. necessity to comply with certain specific
requirements is however organized indirectly, With respect to the transfer of consumer credits, through the supervised institution, which remains article VII.102 of the Code of Economic Law fully responsible for the outsourced services and confirms that « The agreement or the receivables activities, and which will therefore itself take all resulting from the credit agreement can only be necessary measures to supervise the activities assigned to, or, after substitution, only be acquired provided by the external servicer (and, e.g. its ability by a creditor licensed or registered in application of to meet operational requirements and specific this Book, or can be transferred to or acquired by compliance and audit requirements, cf. article 66 of the National Bank of Belgium, the Protection Fund the Banking Law). for Deposits and Financial instruments, credit
insurers , institutions for investment in receivables within the meaning of the Law of 3 August 2012 on undertakings for collective investment which satisfy the conditions laid down in Directive 2009/65/EC i and institutions for investments in receivables, or other persons specifically designated to that purpose by the King”.
The “creditors licensed or registered in application of this Book” are creditors of consumer credits and creditors of mortgage loans (both licenses to be issued by the FSMA). No other institutions or persons were specifically designated by Royal decree so far.
With respect to the transfer of mortgage credits, article VII.147/17 of the Code of Economic Law confirms that: “Without prejudice to the application of articles 1250 and 1251 of the Civil Code, a mortgage credit with movable use (e.g. to acquire a vehicule) or the receivable resulting from such credit agreement can only be assigned to, or, after substitution, only be acquired by a creditor licensed or registered in application of this Book, or can be transferred to or acquired by the National Bank of Belgium, the Protection Fund for Deposits and Financial instruments, credit insurers, institutions for investment in receivables within the meaning of article 2 of the Law of 3 August 2012 on various measures to facilitate the mobilization of receivables in the financial sector, or other persons specifically designated to that purpose by the King”.
The “creditors licensed or registered in application of this Book” are creditors of consumer credits and creditors of mortgage loans (both licenses to be issued by the FSMA). No other institutions or persons were specifically designated by Royal decree so far.
BG None If the activity of acquiring loans represents 30% and Loan servicers NPL purchasers
more of the activity of the buyer and it is by occupation, a registration into a public register of the BNB is required under art. 3a of Law on credit institutions. The legislation determines requirements about the qualification, experience and reputation of the managers and qualifying shareholders. The minimum threshold of the registered capital and the equity of the financial institution shall be maintained above BGN 1 000 000 (500 000 EUR) on an ongoing basis. The origin of the capital funds shall be legitimate and transparent The BNB does not apply prudential supervision for the financial institutions. form of incorporation – Ltd, JSC, location of headquarters or incorporation in BG, ability to meet certain compliance
CZ none none DK The servicer is not required to obtain a full or A buyer of a loan or a portfolio of loans is not
restricted banking license. The servicer is required to obtain a full or restricted banking license furthermore not required to meet any “fit and proper” or required to meet any “fit and proper” requirements. requirements. If the buyer is not already registered according to the AML regulation in Denmark, registration according to this is a requirement
DE Based on Art. 25a KWG and MaRisk (AT 9), the The purchase of loan receivables in execution of a service provider has to provide sufficient resources sales contract does not constitute credit business in and expertise to perform the outsourced activities the meaning of § 1 According to the constant
and processes in an appropriate manner. administrative practice of BaFin the contractual transference of the loan relationship between originator and borrower on the credit buyer and borrower (only possible with the approval of the borrower) in execution of the sale contract isn’t looked as loan business.
Both activities are usually considered as "factoring", thus, an activity requiring a license. However, the license requirement is only triggered when there is a framework agreement between the seller (bank) and the purchaser (factoring company) - aside from the concrete sale of claims. The framework agreement does not have to exist in written form. In the case of a transfer of individual NPL portfolios (without a framework agreement) to investors or servicers, the German Financial Supervisory Authority (BaFin) decides on a case-by-case basis whether it considers the activity in question to be "factoring" requiring a banking license.
EE none commercial activity is the criterion for triggering the possible licensing/permit requirement
IE the servicer is required to comply with specific There are no licensing or regulatory requirements in requirements to legally perform the activities. relation to the acquisition and holding of a loan
Under the Consumer Protection (Regulation of portfolio. However, depending on the nature of the Credit Servicing Firms) Act 2015 which was enacted loans, the transferee may be required to: on 8 July 2015 only entities that have an appropriate be authorised as credit servicing firm to service the licence can conduct credit servicing. This legislation loans itself; or was brought in to ensure that borrowers whose appoint an authorised credit servicing firm to loans were sold by a regulated lender to an service the loans on its behalf. unregulated entity maintained the same level of protection as they had prior to the sale of the loan. Under the legislation the unregulated loan owner is required to appoint an authorised credit servicing Loan servicers NPL purchasers firm to service the loan portfolio. Entities that provide credit servicing include: 1. An entity that holds a licence to grant credit, i.e. a licensed bank, retail credit firm or moneylender; and 2. An authorised Credit Servicing Firm Pre-Approval Control functions have to go through the fitness and probity regime by submitting an Individual Questionnaire. The firm is to be incorporated in the State. The legislation also allows them to set up a branch in the State also, for example, if a firm is based in the UK, the firm can then set up a branch in Ireland.
EL - ability to meet specific compliance and audit According to law 4354/2015 (article 1, par.1b), the requirements following requirements apply to the buyer (Loan - other Transferring Companies) :
The servicing companies are required to comply with
the following requirements: They are Greek companies under the legal form of Société Anonyme or
• They are Greek companies under the legal
form of Société Anonyme or companies established companies established in any other EEA
in any other EEA (European Economic Area) (European Economic Area) Member-state or companies domiciled in third countries,
Member-state which operate in Greece through a which may at their discretion operate in branch Greece through a branch, provided that
• Their scope of activity must be limited
specifically and explicitly to servicing of loans they are not domiciled in countries with
• They must be granted a special operating “favourable” tax regimes or “noncooperating” according to Greek tax law
license for the above purpose by the Bank of 4172/2013. Greece, which also remains the sole competent
authority exercising supervision throughout their Their scope of activity must explicitly active operating status include the acquisition of loans and credit.
• They are registered in the General They are capable of loan/credit acquisitions only Commercial Registry (G.E.MH.) under the condition that they have signed a loan • Their license is published in the management agreement with a servicing company
Governmental Gazette. properly licensed and supervised by the Bank of Greece. Loan Transferring Companies themselves
The Bank of Greece Executive Committee Act No are not required to obtain any operating license.
118/19.5.2016 specifies the criteria, conditions and supporting documentation with respect to the licensing procedure for the establishment and operation of the servicing companies. According to the above mentioned Act, the servicing companies are distinguished into two different categories: the “simple” servicing companies and the ones that are authorized to provide refinancing. For the refinancing servicing companies the requirements are the same as other financial institutions operating in Greece, i.e. leasing, factoring and consumer credit companies. More specifically, it is required that these companies need to comply with the fit and proper requirements for their management body members and for their shareholders, with governance requirements equivalent to banks and initial capital of four million five hundred thousand euro (€4,500,000). The “simple” servicing companies have less requirements such as a lighter fit and proper framework and a few governance requirements such as a written policy to prevent conflicts of interest and initial capital of one hundred thousand euro (€100,000).
Loan servicers NPL purchasers All companies should be AML compliant and have a detailed report setting out the basic principles and methods ensuring the success of forbearance/restructuring solutions; such report shall not be required where the firm carries out servicing business on behalf of a credit or financial institution supervised by the Bank of Greece that is primarily obliged to meet this requirement.
ES The servicer is not legally required to comply with none specific requirements, as there are no specific
regulations on the servicing activity. Whether the outsourcing is deemed to affect core functions or services, credit institutions shall formally notify the competent authority, at least one month in advance, of their plans to delegate those functions or services. This notification shall be accompanied by the related analysis of risks and of the mitigating measures. The competent authority, depending on the nature or criticality of certain functions or activities, may establish additional limitations on the delegation.
FR Les exigences dépendront du caractère échu ou non Dans le cas de créances non échues, l’acquéreur de la créance et du caractère amiable ou exerce une activité réglementée et doit donc avoir contentieux du recouvrement (étant entendu que le été autorisé dans les conditions suivantes : -
recouvrement forcé ne peut porter que sur créance banking licence, meet certain "fit and proper" liquide ou exigible et ne peut se faire que sur la base criteria, specific form of incorporation, location of d’un titre exécutoire dont la délivrance constitue le headquarters or incorporation, ability to préalable). Restricted baking license: pour les meet operational requirements, ability to meet sociétés de financement qui ont été agréées pour certain compliance and audit requirements, réaliser des opérations d’affacturage (étant entendu accounting requirements (i.e. do buyers have to que les autres entités autorisées à réaliser des comply with IFRS or national GAAP provisions?) opérations de crédit sont soumises aux règles qui leurs sont propres).
IT 172 debt collection license held with police office Non-banks should fulfil simplified capital requirements. An
investor needs to partner with a local management company in order to comply with national regulation, the securitization law strictly requires the establishment of a local SPV
HR there are no specific regulation that regulates loan there are no requirements for the buyer. servicers.
CY There is no specific requirement for the servicer. According to the Law regulating the Sale of Credit For outsourcing applications (the bank will outsource Facilities and Other Related Issues, only the the servicing of loans to a third party) the following following legal persons are allowed to acquire credit are required: facilities that are less than 1 mln:
-
-Description of the services (A) A credit acquiring company, including an asset - Details of the provider (in this case the management company, incorporated in the
servicer) Republic, which has obtained authorisation from the - A risk assessment by the bank that has to Central Bank.
carry out for the tasks will outsource In order to obtain authorisation, the company must Specific conditions of the contract submit information to the Central Bank
demonstrating amongst others, that it fulfils certain
172 Information from industry source in public consultation.
Loan servicers NPL purchasers “fit and proper” criteria, operational and organisational requirements and any other information as deemed necessary by the Central Bank which are reflected in the Law. (B) An authorised credit institution (C) A credit institution that is authorised and supervised by the competent authority of another member state, which has the right, by virtue of section 10A of the Business of Credit Institutions Law, to provide services or to establish a branch in the Republic.
(D) A financial institution, which is a subsidiary of a credit institution incorporated in a member state and which provides its services in the Republic or operates in the Republic through a branch, under the provisions laid down in section 10Bbis of the Business of Credit Institutions Law.
HU restricted banking licence, specific form of restricted banking licence, specific form of incorporation, -ability to meet specific compliance incorporation, -ability to meet specific compliance and audit requirements, trigger is commercial activity and audit requirements
MT Third party service permits are not known to exist. a buyer of a loan is expected to be authorised by BR/14 requires that if the service being outsourced the Authority to carry out the activity of lending
is lending, a banking licence is required under the Financial Institution’s Act and/or the Banking Act [banking rule BR/14 principle 4.1]
LU 173 There is a licensing and regulatory regime in place to enable non-banks to recover/manage debts
(including NPLs)
LT no special requirements. General contract law No specific requirements are needed for a buyer provisions shall be applied acquiring a defaulted loan where the contract
agreement is terminated; In case of performing household loans (either unsecured or secured), the acquirer must have a licence of a credit provider, i.e. a consumer credit provider licence, a banking licence or a restricted banking licence. In case of performing corporate loans, no specific requirements are in place.
LV A provider of debt recovery services is entitled to The Civil Law does not regulate such matters. Only recover a debt in the name of or on behalf of a general provisions for different kind of contracts are creditor, if it has registered as a merchant or a included in the Civil Law which are applicable to any performer of professional activities and has contractual party.
received a special permit (licence) for debt recovery. The Consumer Rights Protection Centre shall issue the special permit (licence).
NL In the Act on Financial Supervision (Wet op het There is a duty for companies to have a license if financieel toezicht (Wft)) there is a duty for they offer credit. In case of a transfer of a loan, the companies to have a licence from the Authority of new owner is the one who ‘offers’ the credit. In such Financial Markets (AFM) or a waiver, if they act as a case a license is needed. There are however
an agent in the establishment of (loan) agreements waivers, such as for Special Purpose Vehicles (SPVs). In that case the new owner has outsourced
173 ECB/SSM (2017) Loan servicers NPL purchasers between lenders and consumers In some cases the management to a party that has a license as a debt collectors need a license (to renegotiate credit intermediary or a waiver, for example for terms of an agreement on behalf of the lender), but credit institutions this is not always the case since waivers also apply (for example if the agent purely collects payments).
AT It depends on the activities performed; in case of Specific requirements need to be fulfilled, for pure outsourcing, no specific requirements instance in the case of purchase of receivables necessary. Otherwise i.e. in the case of factoring, a (factoring) but also other set ups might be possible banking license would be required. If a banking (SPV) and depending on the funding and
transaction is performed as listed in Art. 1 BWG, a construction/transactions performed, a full banking banking license is required license might be necessary
PL 174 Authorisation required an Alternative Investment Fund Management structure is
required in order to invest in portfolios from the supervised industry
PT According to article 5(2) of the Portuguese Under Portuguese banking law there is no specific Securitisation Law, the Portuguese Securities legal framework regulating the transfer of bank
Market Commission (Comissão do Mercado de loans. However, since lending is legally qualified as Valores Mobiliários or CMVM) can authorise a loan a restricted activity, only credit institutions or servicer other than the Seller. The Law does not financial companies may acquire such loans on a establish specific requirements, but the servicer is professional basis without it being considered required to meet certain ‘fit and proper’ criteria, and indirect lending. adequate human and operational resources. For the Nevertheless, the transfer of bank loans is not servicer to grant new credit (fresh money), it must be considered indirect lending if those are already nona credit institution, since only credit institutions may performing loans. Therefore, the answers below rely grant credit professionally. on the assumption that the transferred loans in question are not non-performing loans, since none of these restrictions would otherwise be applicable.
RO The entities performing debt recovery activity need In order to legally acquire a performing loan, the to be registered with the National Authority for buyer is required to be a creditor (is required a full Consumer Protection. In case of refinancing full banking licence in case of a credit institution or the banking licence is required, according to the registration as a non-bank professional creditor in banking legal framework, when the loan servicer is the NBR registers). fit and proper criteria for nonnot allowed to carry out lending activities in bank professional creditors are regulated. entities accordance with the relevant applicable legal need to be incorporated as joint-stock commercial framework. companies. Regarding the NPLs for individuals, the
Neither the loan servicers nor the loan servicing transferee (which can be only an entity performing activities are regulated by Romanian legislation debt recovery activity) is required to have its head related to non-bank professional creditors. office, a branch or a representative in Romania for
solving potentials disputes and for being held liable in front of public authorities. The persons responsible for managing the activity shall be of good repute, knowledge and competence requirements for staff should be required, the remuneration structure of the staff should not be solely contingent on the achievement of recovery targets, nor should it be correlated solely with the amounts recovered.
SI There are no special requirements for providers of There are no specific requirements for buyers to loan services per se. legally acquire a loan except in case of consumer credit – the buyer has to be authorised to provide consumer credit. A bank may also transfer a
174 Information from industry source in public consultation Loan servicers NPL purchasers consumer credit to a buyer established as: - the insurance company (in order to repay the creditor for overdue credit obligations of the collateral), - the special purpose vehicle for securitisation, - the special purpose vehicle for the management non-performing loans
SK The servicing of loans is not recognised as a In case of transfer in the virtue of Art. 92(8) of Act separate activity and it falls under the definition of No 483/2001 Coll. there are no requirements as it providing credit and loans. The servicing of a loan does not have to be a bank. For the transfer via is considered as a banking activity requiring a refinancing of the loan the same requirements as banking license for the loan originator apply.
According to Art. 17 of Act 129/2010 Coll. the consumer credits can be transferred on a creditor with a full authorisation to provide consumer credits, bank, foreign bank or a branch of a foreign bank or on a third party in case of a claim of a past due consumer credit or a claim which became due before the consumer credit due date is transferred or assigned.
SE A person who collects debts on behalf of another A person who collects debts on behalf of another person, or collects debts which have been taken person, or collects debts which have been taken over for collection, normally requires a permit from over for collection, normally requires a permit from the Data Inspection Board. Before permission is the Data Inspection Board.
granted, the company must have in its employment a person with professional legal experience of debt collection. The Data Protection Authority determines whether the conditions are met. Debt collecting must be conducted in a professional and judicious manner. The Data Protection Authority ensures that these rules are adhered to. This is achieved by inspections.
SF No [specific] requirements. The Act on collection of No special requirements the payments gives some guidelines how to collect
the payment with ordinary way UK Mortgages: Permission to be a mortgage If a firm purchases a debt, and so becomes the
administrator will require a firm to meet “fit and creditor, it needs permission for exercising, or proper” criteria, specific form of incorporation, having the right to exercise, the lender’s rights and location of headquarters or incorporation, ability to duties under a regulated credit agreement (Article meet operational, specific compliance and audit 60B(2)). requirements as well as additional conduct Regulated mortgages: If the buyer does not expect requirements. to enter into new regulated mortgage contracts they
Consumer credit: a firm wishing to be authorised do not need any regulatory permissions – providing will need to meet the threshold conditions, they appoint a regulated firm to administer the
including suitability, business model and effective contracts purchased. supervision. There are also specific conduct of .
business rules in the Consumer Credit (CONC) module of our Handbook.
21 Mar '18 |
Proposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL on credit servicers, credit purchasers and the recovery of collateral PROPOSAL |
Secretary-General of the European Commission 7403/18 |
The EU Monitor enables its users to keep track of the European process of lawmaking, focusing on the relevant dossiers. It automatically signals developments in your chosen topics of interest. Apologies to unregistered users, we can no longer add new users.This service will discontinue in the near future.